Skip to main content

An Integrative Framework of Influences on Behavior

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Design of Incentive Systems

Part of the book series: Contributions to Management Science ((MANAGEMENT SC.))

Abstract

The goals of this chapter are (1) to introduce important theories and concepts which are employed in the discussion on the hypotheses of incentive and sorting effects in Chap. 4, (2) to introduce existing economic frameworks in order to get an overview of potential contingencies concerning incentive and sorting effects, and (3) to identify literature gaps in the observation of contingency variables and develop an integrative framework of variables under investigation in the experiment. The integrative framework guides the discussion on the experimental design in Chap. 3 particularly concerning environmental variables and is specified in Chaps. 4 and 5 particularly concerning individual variables. The three goals are addressed in the subsequent three sub-sections.

Behaviour cannot be invented in the armchair. It has to be observed.

Reinhard Selten (1930 Breslau)

Selten (1998), p. 414

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    More recently prescriptive decision theory has been suggested to be a third area of decision making research. In particular, business practice might be interested in this field of decision making, because its aim is to support decision makers in their decisions. As it is not meant to deal with tools for improving decision quality in this text, prescriptive decision theory is not introduced as single area of decision research (Cf. Goodwin et al. (1994)). Moreover, in some literature normative and prescriptive decision theory is used interchangeably (Cf. Bamberg and Coenenberg (2002), p. 1).

  2. 2.

    A prominent critic of the assumption of unbounded rationality is Simon (1955).

  3. 3.

    Cf. Laux (1998), p. 2; Bamberg and Coenenberg (2002), pp. 1ff.

  4. 4.

    Cf. Eisenführ and Weber (1993), p. 2; Laux (1998), p. 2.

  5. 5.

    This is only selective and very brief presentation of relevant theories. For instance, the social cognition theory is not considered (Cf. Wood and Bandura (1989)). For this and further psychological theories and discussion refer to Gerhart and Rynes (2003), pp. 119 ff., Birnberg et al. (2007) or Pinder (2008). For the transaction cost theory refer e.g. to Williamson (1981).

  6. 6.

    In literature psychological theories related to motivation are also often classified into content-based or process-based theories. Content-based theories deal with characteristics, contents and structure of motives, whereas process-based theories try to explain the emergence of motivation and its effects on behavior. Need hierarchy, two factor theory and cognitive evaluation theory can be classified as part of the content-based group; expectancy, goal-setting or equity theory generally belong to the process-based group of theories (Cf. Staehle et al. (1999), pp. 218ff.; Brandenberg (2001), p. 76).

  7. 7.

    The classification in Fig. 2.1 is not necessarily free of overlap. For instance, by means of the agency theory statements about the general importance of money can be inferred, too.

  8. 8.

    Cf. Sorger (2000), pp. 1ff.; Bonner (2008), p. 28.

  9. 9.

    Cf. von Neumann and Morgenstern (1947); Savage (1954) drawn from Sorger (2000).

  10. 10.

    Cf. Kahneman and Tversky (1979).

  11. 11.

    Cf. Eichenberger (1992); Further, refer to Allais (1953) or Ellsberg (1961) for early studies about violations to expected utility theory or to Tversky and Kahneman (1981) for an anomaly called the framing effect.

  12. 12.

    Cf. Gerhart and Rynes (2003), pp. 48ff.; Cather (2010), pp. 127ff.; Refer to Read (2007), pp. 45ff. for utility in a historical context.

  13. 13.

    Cf. Maslow (1943); Herzberg (1968); Deci and Ryan (1985) drawn from Pinder (2008), pp. 71ff., 86ff., 208ff.

  14. 14.

    Cf. Lambert (2007), p. 247.

  15. 15.

    Cf. Young and Lewis (1995), p. 56; Gerhart and Rynes (2003), pp. 8, 138; see also Sprinkle and Williamson (2007), who structure their review of experiments in management accounting according to agency principles.

  16. 16.

    Cf. Macho-Stadler et al. (2005), p. 5.

  17. 17.

    Cf. Jensen and Meckling (1976); Fama (1980); Petersen (1989), pp. 22ff.; Frese (1992), pp. 71ff.; Gibbons (1998), pp. 2f.; Laffont and Martimort (2002); Macho-Stadler et al. (2005), pp. 1, 4; Salanié (2005), pp. 5f.

  18. 18.

    Cf. Demski and Feltham (1978); Milgrom and Roberts (1992), pp. 149 ff., 166 ff.

  19. 19.

    Cf. Bamberg and Ballwieser (1987, pp. 9 ff.; Saam (2007), p. 827; Küpper (2008), pp. 83 ff.; Refer also to Saam (2007), pp. 826–829 for a more in depth overview of agency literature.

  20. 20.

    Cf. Baiman (1990), pp. 342f.

  21. 21.

    Cf. Milgrom and Roberts (1992), pp. 186f.; Brickley et al. (2009), pp. 459f.

  22. 22.

    Cf. Milgrom and Roberts (1992), pp. 166ff.

  23. 23.

    Cf. Milgrom and Roberts (1992), pp. 149ff.; Macho-Stadler et al. (2005), pp. 11f.; Early important contributions to adverse selection problems come from Akerlof (1970); Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976). For an overview to markets with asymmetric information refer to Lofgren et al. (2002).

  24. 24.

    Cf. Spence (1973); Salop and Salop (1976); Spence (1976).

  25. 25.

    Cf. e.g. Demski and Feltham (1978); Fama (1980).

  26. 26.

    Cf. Fischer (1995), p. 321.

  27. 27.

    Cf. Baiman (1990), pp. 344ff.

  28. 28.

    Cf. Baiman (1990), p. 345.

  29. 29.

    Cf. Demski and Feltham (1978), pp. 339f.; Sprinkle (2003).

  30. 30.

    Cf. Laux (1998), p. 2; Bamberg and Coenenberg (2002), pp. 1ff.; Lambert (2007).

  31. 31.

    Cf. Young and Lewis (1995), p. 57.

  32. 32.

    Cf. Allais (1953); Simon (1955); Herzberg et al. (1959), p. 114.

  33. 33.

    Cf. Ashton und Ashton (1995b), pp. 57f.

  34. 34.

    Cf. Weiner (1996), p. 219.

  35. 35.

    Cf. Wiemann (1998), p. 36; Brandenberg (2001), p. 67; Heide (2001); Pinder (2008).

  36. 36.

    Cf. Lewin (1946); Rotter (1954); Atkinson (1974); For comprehensive reviews of this literature refer to Weiner (1996), pp. 153ff. or Beckmann and Heckhausen (2006); For a review of Vroom (1964)’s theory refer to Pinder (2008), pp. 363ff.

  37. 37.

    Cf. Ryan (1958); Locke (1968); For a review of goal directed theories refer to Pinder (2008), pp. 389ff.

  38. 38.

    Cf. Adams (1963).

  39. 39.

    Refer for instance to Waller (1985); Camerer and Hogarth (1999); Bonner and Sprinkle (2002), p. 304 or Bonner (2008).

  40. 40.

    Cf. Waller and Chow (1985), p. 461.

  41. 41.

    Cf. Waller and Chow (1985), p. 461.

  42. 42.

    Cf. Camerer and Hogarth (1999).

  43. 43.

    Cf. Smith and Walker (1993).

  44. 44.

    Cf. Camerer and Hogarth (1999), p. 9.

  45. 45.

    Cf. Camerer and Hogarth (1999).

  46. 46.

    Bonner and Sprinkle (2002) use the term performance for indicating human accomplishments within laboratory experiments. In this research the term productivity is preferred, because it not only considers output but also input by definition. However, within experiments the terms can be often used interchangeably and express an output measured within and against certain standards. As will be explained below, productivity in the present experiment is defined by the amount of anagrams solved correctly (output) within 10 minutes (input) for one participant.

  47. 47.

    In their research performance has to be quantifiable, i.e. it needs to be measured according to a certain standard. This implicitly means that results of multi-person environments or markets are not considered in this study. Tasks including decisions between lotteries or certainty equivalents are not included, because of the problem of setting a normative performance standard.

  48. 48.

    Cf. Bonner and Sprinkle (2002), p. 304; In Bonner (2008), p. 198 the framework is similar. A main difference is that the incentive-scheme category is subsumed in environmental variables.

  49. 49.

    Bonner and Sprinkle (2002), p. 311.

  50. 50.

    Cf. Bonner and Sprinkle (2002).

  51. 51.

    Cf. Bonner (2008).

  52. 52.

    Cf. Bonner (2008).

  53. 53.

    Refer to Camerer (1995), pp. 652ff. for a review on framing effects.

  54. 54.

    Cf. Bonner (2008), p. 88.

  55. 55.

    Cf. Camerer and Hogarth (1999), p. 9.

  56. 56.

    Cf. Bailey and Fessler (2008).

  57. 57.

    As task difficulty is not measured objectively by taking different tasks, but subjectively by prompting individuals’ perception of task difficulty, it can be considered as an individual contingency (cf. Waller and Chow (1985), pp. 461f.). However, as the subjective perception reflects the influence of task difficulty in general, in the framework it is placed as environmental determinant. Task attractiveness is considered indirectly through elements of individuals’interest in a task (Cf. 4.2.1, 4.2.2.3).

  58. 58.

    Cf. Cadsby et al. (2007), p. 388; Hyatt and Taylor (2008), p. 42.

  59. 59.

    Cf. Bonner (2008), pp. 100ff.

  60. 60.

    Cf. Bonner (2008), p. 103.

  61. 61.

    Cf. Bonner and Sprinkle (2002), pp. 313ff.; Lazear (2004).

  62. 62.

    Cf. Bonner et al. (2000), p. 40; Gerhart and Rynes (2003), pp. 151f.; Chiappori and Salanié (2003), p. 116; Lazear (2004), p. 21; Cadsby et al. (2007), p. 387; Eriksson and Villeval (2008), pp. 412f.

  63. 63.

    Rotter (1954), p. 85.

  64. 64.

    Cf. Lewin (1946); Rotter (1954), p. 85.

  65. 65.

    Cf. Heckhausen (2006), pp. 3ff.; Pinder (2008), p. 3; Refer to von Rosenstiel (1999) for a good text on motivational foundations of incentives and an introduction to relevant motivational theories.

  66. 66.

    Cf. Staehle et al. (1999), pp. 149–164.

  67. 67.

    Cf. Waller and Chow (1985), pp. 461f.

References

  • Adams JS (1963) Towards an understanding of inequity. J Abnorm Psychol 67:422–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA (1970) The market for “Lemons”: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quart J Econ 94(3):749–775

    Google Scholar 

  • Allais M (1953) Le Comportement de l’Homme Rationnel devant le Risque: Critique des Postulats et Axiomes de l’Ecole Americaine Le. Econometrica 21(4):503–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson JW (1974) The mainsprings of achievement-oriented activity. In: Atkinson JW (ed) Motivation and achievement. Wiley, New York, pp 13–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey CD, Fessler NJ (eds) (2008) An experimental examination of the moderating effects of task complexity and task attractiveness on the effectiveness of monetary incentives during performance of repeated tasks. Working paper, The university of Memphis, University of central Missouri

    Google Scholar 

  • Baiman S (1990) Agency research in managerial accounting: a second look. Acc Org Soc 15(4):341–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bamberg G, Ballwieser W (1987) Agency theory, information, and incentives. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bamberg G, Coenenberg AG (2002) Betriebswirtschaftliche Entscheidungslehre, 11th edn. Vahlen, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckmann J, Heckhausen H (2006) Motivation durch erwartung und anreiz. In: Heckhausen J, Heckhausen H (eds) Motivation und handeln. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 105–142

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Birnberg JG, Luft J, Shields MD (2007) Psychology theory in management accounting research. In: Chapman CSM, Hopwood AG, Shields MD (eds) Handbook of management accounting research. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 113–135

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonner SE (2008) Judgment and decision making in accounting. Pearson/Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonner SE, Sprinkle GB (2002) The effects of monetary incentives on effort and task performance: theories, evidence and a framework for research. Account Org Soc 27(4–5):303–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonner SE, Hastie R, Sprinkle GB, Young SM (2000) A review of the effects of financial incentives on performance in laboratory tasks: implications for management accounting. J Manage Account Res 12:19–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandenberg A (2001) Anreizsysteme zur Unternehmenssteuerung: Gestaltungsoptionen, motivationstheoretische Herausforderungen und Lösungsansätze. Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Brickley JA, Smith CW, Zimmerman JL (2009) Managerial economics and organizational architecture, 5th edn. McGraw-Hill Irwin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Cadsby CB, Song F, Tapon F (2007) Sorting and incentive effects of pay for performance: an experimental investigation. Acad Manage J 50(2):387–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (1995) Individual decision making. In: Kagel JH, Roth AE (eds) The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 587–704

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Hogarth R (1999) The effects of financial incentives in experiments: a review and capital-labor-production framework. J Risk Uncertainty 19(1–3):7–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cather DA (2010) A gentle introduction to risk aversion and utility theory. Risk Manage Insur Rev 13(1):127–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori J-C, Salanié B (2003) Advances in economics and econometrics. testing contract theory: a survey of some recent work. In: Dewatripont M, Hansen LP, Turnovsky SJ (eds) Advances in economics and econometrics. theory and applications; eighth world congress. Cambridge University Press (Econometric Society monographs, No. 35), Cambridge, pp 115–149

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Deci EL, Ryan RM (1985) Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. Plenum, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Demski JS, Feltham GA (1978) Economic incentives in budgetary control systems. Account Rev 53(2):336–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichenberger R (1992) Verhaltensanomalien und Wirtschaftswissenschaft: Herausforderung, Reaktionen, Perspektiven. Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenführ F, Weber M (1993) Rationales entscheiden. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg D (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q J Econ 75(4):643–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson T, Villeval MC (2008) Performance-pay, sorting and social motivation. J Econ Behav Organ 68(2):412–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF (1980) Agency problems and the theory of the firm. J Polit Econ 88(2):288–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer M (1995) Agency-theorie. Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium 6:320–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Frese E (ed) (1992) Enzyklopädie der Betriebswirtschaftslehre, 3. ed. Stuttgart: Poeschel (Enzyklopädie der Betriebswirtschaftslehre, Vol. 2)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerhart BA, Rynes S (2003) Compensation: theory, evidence, and strategic implications. Sage, Thousand Oaks

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R (ed) (1998) Incentives in organizations. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, 6695, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin P, Wright G, Phillips LD (1994) Decision analysis for management judgment, Reprinted. Chichester u.a

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckhausen J (2006) Motivation und handeln: einführung und Überblick. In: Heckhausen J, Heckhausen H (eds) Motivation und handeln, 3rd edn. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 1–10

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Heide T (2001) Informationsökonomische und verhaltenswissenschaftliche Ansätze als Beitrag zu einer theoretischen Fundierung des Controlling: Eine vergleichende Analyse anhand ausgewählter Beispiele. Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzberg F (1968) One more time: how do you motivate employees? Harv Bus Rev 46(1):53–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzberg F, Mausner B, Snyderman BB (1959) The motivation to work, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyatt TA, Taylor MH (2008) The effects of incomplete personal capability knowledge and overconfidence on employment contract selection. Behav Res Account 20(2):37–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3(4):305–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2):1039–1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Küpper H.-U (2008) Controlling: Konzeption, Aufgaben, Instrumente, 5. ed. Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J, Martimort D (2002) The theory of incentives: the principal-agent model. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert RA (2007) Elsevier. In: Chapman CSM, Hopwood AG, Shields MD (eds) Handbook of management accounting research. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 247–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Laux H (1998) Entscheidungstheorie, 4th edn. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (2004) Output-based pay: incentives, retention or sorting. In: Polachek SW (ed) Accounting for worker well-being. Elsevier JAI (Research in labor economics, 23), Amsterdam, pp 1–25

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lewin K (1946) Action research and minority problems. J Soc Issues 2:34–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke EA (1968) Toward a theory of task motivation and incentives. Organ Behav Hum Perform 3(2):157–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lofgren K-G, Persson T, Weibull JW (2002) Markets with asymmetric information: the contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz. Scand J Econ 104(2):195–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler I, Pérez-Castrillo JD, Watt R (2005) An introduction to the economics of information: incentives and contracts, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Maslow AH (1943) A theory of human motivation. Psychol Rev 50:370–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom PR, Roberts J (1992) Economics, organization and management. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen T (1989) Optimale Anreizsysteme: Betriebswirtschaftliche Implikationen der Prinzipal-Agenten-Theorie: Univ., Diss.--Bonn, 1988. Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinder CC (2008) Work motivation in organizational behavior, 2nd edn. Psychology Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Read D (2007) Experienced utility: utility theory from Jeremy Bentham to Daniel Kahneman. Think Reason 13(1):45–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstiel L von (1999) Motivationale Grundlagen von Anreizsystemen. In: Bühler, Wolfgang (ed, 1999): Unternehmenssteuerung und Anzeizsysteme. Kongress-Dokumentation. Stuttgart: Schäffer-Poeschel (Schriftenreihe der Schmalenbach-Gesellschaft), pp 47–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild M, Stiglitz J (1976) Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: an essay on the economics of imperfect information. Q J Econ 90(4):629–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotter JB (1954) Social learning and clinical psychology. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan TA (1958) Drives, tasks, and the initiation of behavior. Am J Psychol 71:74–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saam NJ (2007) Asymmetry in information versus asymmetry in power: implicit assumptions of agency theory? J Socio-Econ 36(6):825–840

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salanié B (2005) The economics of contracts: a primer, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop J, Salop S (1976) Self-selection and turnover in the labor market. Q J Econ 90(4):619–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savage L (1954) The foundation of statistics. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1955) A behavioral model of rational choice. Q J Econ 69(1):99–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL, Walker JM (1993) Rewards, experience and decision costs in first price auctions. Econ Inq 31(2):237–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorger G (2000) Entscheidungstheorie bei Unsicherheit: Grundlagen und Anwendungen. Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (1973) Job market signaling. Q J Econ 87(3):355–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (1976) Informational aspects of market structure: an introduction. Q J Econ 90(4):591–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sprinkle GB (2003) Perspectives on experimental research in managerial accounting. Account Organ Soc 28(2–3):287–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sprinkle GB, Williamson MG (2007) Experimental research in managerial accounting. In: Chapman CSM, Hopwood AG, Shields MD (eds) Handbook of management accounting research. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 415–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Staehle WH, Conrad P, Sydow J (1999) Management: Eine verhaltenswissenschaftliche Perspektive, 8th edn. Vahlen, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky A, Kahneman D (1981) The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211(4481):453–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1947) Theory of games and economic behavior, 2nd edn. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Vroom VH (1964) Work and motivation. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Waller WS (1985) Self-selection and the probability of quitting: a contracting approach to employee turnover in public accounting. J Account Res 23(2):817–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waller WS, Chow CW (1985) The self-selection and effort effects of standard-based employment contracts: a framework and some empirical evidence. Account Rev 60(3):458–476

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiner B (1996) Human motivation: metaphors, theories, and research, 2nd edn. Sage, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiemann V (1998) Verlust-Eskalation in Management-Entscheidungen: Eine empirische Untersuchung. Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1981) The economics of organization: the transaction cost approach. Am J Sociol 87(3):548–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood R, Bandura A (1989) Social cognitive theory of organizational management. Acad Manage Rev 14(3):361–384

    Google Scholar 

  • Young SM, Lewis BL (1995) Experimental incentive-contracting research in management accounting. In: Ashton RH, Ashton AH (eds) Judgment and decision-making research in accounting and auditing. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 55–75

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Fehrenbacher, D.D. (2013). An Integrative Framework of Influences on Behavior. In: Design of Incentive Systems. Contributions to Management Science. Physica, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-33599-0_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics