Skip to main content

Control Mechanisms for CRM Systems and Competition Law

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Remuneration of Copyright Owners

Part of the book series: MPI Studies on Intellectual Property and Competition Law ((MSIP,volume 27))

  • 895 Accesses

Abstract

There are basically two different mechanisms to control collective management organizations (CMOs), namely the general competition-law approach and the sector-specific regulation approach. This chapter explains the features of copyright management (CRM) systems in general and discusses up- and downsides of both approaches. In conclusion it suggests a primary focus on sector-specific regulation. This approach not only takes into account the particularities of two-sided markets in which CMOs act as intermediaries, but also allows the balancing of non-economic values and interests which are among the objectives of CMOs. Sector-specific regulation is further capable of addressing governance issues of CMOs; above all, it promotes transparency for both right holders and users by providing ex ante guidance. General competition law, in contrast, applies ex post and is particularly likely to become a last resort to control CMOs.

Reto M. Hilty is Director of the Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition; full Professor ad personam at the University of Zurich; Honorary Professor at the University of Munich.

Tao Li is Junior Research Fellow of the Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    V. Vázquez-Lopez (2010), 689-695; D. Gervais (2010), 17-28; P. Gilliéron (2006), 952-956; R.M. Hilty, S. Nérisson (2013), 222-224.

  2. 2.

    N. Searle, G. White (2013), 45-56.

  3. 3.

    Recital 8 of Directive 2014/26/EU of 26 February 2014 on collective management of copyright and related rights and multi-territorial licensing of rights in musical works for online use in the internal market, 84 OJ L72-98.

  4. 4.

    J. Drexl, S. Nérisson, F. Trumpke, R.M. Hilty (2013), 325-327; J. Drexl (2013), 11, 81.

  5. 5.

    R.M. Hilty (2010), 151; R.M. Hilty, S. Nérisson (2013), 224-225.

  6. 6.

    D. Gervais (2011), 591-617; about competitive deficit and its consequences, see R. Podszun (2014), 179-181.

  7. 7.

    See in particular CJEU, Case 78/70 Deutsche Grammophon v. Metro [1971] ECR 487; Case 127/73 BRT v. SABAM [1974] ECR 313; Cases 55/80 and 57/80 Musikvertrieb Membran GmbH v. GEMA [1981] ECR 147; Case 7/82 GVL v. Commission [1983] ECR 483.

  8. 8.

    In 1941, the United States brought separate antitrust suits against Broadcast Music, Inc. (BMI) and the American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP). Both suits were settled by Consent Decree. See U.S. v. BMI, 1940-43 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 56, 096, 381 (E.D.Wisc.1941); U.S. v. ASCAP, 1940-43 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 56,104, 402 (S.D.N.Y.1941). These Consent Decrees have been amended over time. For the latest amended Consent Decrees see U.S. v. BMI, 1996-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 71, 379 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 1994); U.S. v. ASCAP, 2001-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 73, 474 (S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001).

  9. 9.

    A. Schierholz (2010), 1151-1152.

  10. 10.

    W. Herschel (1967), 26.

  11. 11.

    R.M. Hilty, S. Nérisson (2013), 224-225.

  12. 12.

    S. Besen, S. Kirby, S. Salop (1992), 383-411; R. Merges (1996), 1316-1317; G. Hansen, A. Schmidt-Bischoffshausen (2007), 461-463; J. Drexl (2007), 272.

  13. 13.

    M. Heller (1998), 621-688; M. Kretschmer (2002), 126-137; J. Schovsbo (2012), 170.

  14. 14.

    S. von Lewinski (2005), 401-407; J. Becker (2008), 33-41.

  15. 15.

    P. Katzenberger, S. Nérisson (2011), 283-295; R.M. Hilty, S. Nérisson (2013), 225-226. For economic analyses of the risk-sharing in CMOs see A. Snow, R. Watt (2005), 23-35.

  16. 16.

    See U.S. v. ASCAP, 1940-43 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 56, 104, 402 (S.D.N.Y.1941) (supra n. 8); R.M. Hilty (2012), 35-37.

  17. 17.

    Recital 3 of Directive 2014/26/EU (supra n. 3); A. Schierholz (2010), 1152-1153.

  18. 18.

    European Affairs (2006), 30.

  19. 19.

    European Affairs (2006), 39; J. Becker (2008), 33-40.

  20. 20.

    A. Katz (2005), 12-18.

  21. 21.

    R. Podszun (2014), 181.

  22. 22.

    G. Hansen, A. Schmidt-Bischoffshausen (2007), 470.

  23. 23.

    J. Drexl (2014), 263-268.

  24. 24.

    R. Podszun (2014), 181.

  25. 25.

    K. Viscusi, E. Joseph, M. John (2005), 401.

  26. 26.

    Examples of agreements between CMOs to limit competition in this field are the Santiago and the Barcelona Agreement; see Commission Recommendation 2005/737/EC of 18 May 2015 on collective cross-border management of copyright and related rights for legitimate online music service, OJ L 276/54; see also Commission Decision of 16 July 2008 relating to a proceeding under Article 81 of the EC Treaty and Article 53 of the Agreement on the European Economic Area (Case COMP/C2/38.698—CISAC).

  27. 27.

    SESAC was established by the right holders from Europe whom ASCAP refused to accept as members; BMI was established by the radio broadcasters, for whom ASCAP tried to double its tariffs. See J. Drexl (2013), 217.

  28. 28.

    In the US, most of the cases concerning cartel issues are settled by “Consent Decree”; for more details about the legal effect of a Consent Decree see R. Epstein (2007), 1-14; T. Lindstrom, K. Tighe (1974), IX.

  29. 29.

    Para. X. A. of the ASCAP Consent Decree: U.S. v. ASCAP, 2001-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 73, 474 (S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001) (supra n. 8).

  30. 30.

    Id., para. VI.

  31. 31.

    Id., para. IV. A.

  32. 32.

    Id., para. IX. D-E.

  33. 33.

    There are only a few countries in the world that follow the US approach, for instance Ireland and Poland; see e.g. Irish Competition Authority, Decision No. 326 of 18 May 1994, Notification No. CA/2/91E—Performing Right Society and individual creators/publishers (Assignment of Copyright), para. 81; Poland: UOKiK, Decision of 16 July 2004, Case RWA‐21/2004, Annual Report 2006, 20.

  34. 34.

    The CRJ were set up under the Copyright Royalty and Distribution Reform Act of 2004. CRJ have to apply § 801(b)(1) of the US Copyright Act according to which “reasonable … rates of royalty payments … shall be calculated to achieve the following objectives:

    (A) To maximize the availability of creative works to the public.

    (B) To afford the copyright owner a fair return for his or her creative work and the copyright user a fair income under existing economic conditions.

    (C) To reflect the relative roles of the copyright owner and the copyright user in the product made available to the public with respect to relative creative contribution, technological contribution, capital investment, cost, risk, and contribution to the opening of new markets for creative expression and media for their communication.

    (D) To minimize any disruptive impact on the structure of the industries involved and on generally prevailing industry practices.”

  35. 35.

    D. Gervais (2011), 610-613; G. Lunney (2010), 333-334; NN (1978), Note CBS v. ASCAP, 802; G. Clark (1980), 749.

  36. 36.

    A. Dietz (1978), 237-239; J. Fujitani (1984), 134-136.

  37. 37.

    In some jurisdictions, there are no substantive regulations or acts on CRM systems, but copyright act paragraphs concerning CMOs. For example, in Part IV of the British Copyright Act under the title “Performing Right Tribunal”, in Part V of the Irish Copyright Act under the title “Jurisdiction of the Comptroller of Industrial and Commercial Property” and in Part VIII of the Copyright Ordinance of Hong Kong under the title “Copyright Licensing” (Articles 145-168).

  38. 38.

    Although Germany was not the first jurisdiction to undertake such a specific regulatory framework related to CMOs and to provide special procedural rules in order to handle conflicts between the parties involved. As early as 1932, the Netherlands established a specific arrangement by introducing Article 30a and Article 35a to the Copyright Act and by a related regulation. For more details about the history of CMOs in the Netherlands see A. Dietz (1978), 234-237.

  39. 39.

    J. Fujitani (1984), 132; A. Dietz (1978), 219.

  40. 40.

    On 9 June 2015 the German Federal Ministry of Justice and Consumer Protection officially published a first draft and explanatory notes to seek public opinion, available at: www.bmjv.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/pdfs/Gesetze/RefE_Richtlinie_Umsetzungsgesetz.pdf?__blob=publicationFile. The consolidated text of the draft has 6 chapters and 139 articles, while the law of 1965 has 4 chapters and 36 articles. This VGG amendment has been completed in May 2016 (BGBl. I S. 1190).

  41. 41.

    A. Dietz (1978), 234; BT-Drucksache IV/ 271 (1962), 12.

  42. 42.

    On the one hand, CMOs are obliged by law to contract with users under certain equal conditions (Section 11 of German Act on the Administration of Copyright and Related Rights); on the other hand, CMOs have the duty to contract with right holders under certain equal conditions (Section 6), and to disclose related information regularly (Section 9).

  43. 43.

    Decision of the Commission: 71/224/EEC of the Commission of 2 June 1971; CJEU, Case IV/26.760—GEMA, [1971] OJ 134/15.

  44. 44.

    D. Gerber (1994), 98.

  45. 45.

    For further details see A. Schierholz (2010), 1164-1166.

  46. 46.

    J. Drexl, S. Nérisson, F. Trumpke, R.M. Hilty (2013), 325-328. Indirectly, however, sector-specific competition law as established through Directive 2014/26/EU to a certain degree may also have harmonizing effects on substantive (national) copyright legislations.

  47. 47.

    For more about the tasks and functions of CMOs in the future, see K.-N. Peifer (2015), 34-35.

  48. 48.

    R.M. Hilty (2010), 148.

  49. 49.

    Supply-side substitutability is only taken into consideration when “its effects are equivalent to those of demand-side substitutability in terms of effectiveness and immediacy”. See J. Drexl (2013), 75; The EU Commission notice on the definition of relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law (1997), OJ No. C 273, 5, para. 20.

  50. 50.

    J. Drexl (2013), 75; M. Lamping (2015), 123-124; see also Case 89/205/EES, Magill TV Guide, 1989 ECR L 78/43, para. 20.

  51. 51.

    J. Drexl (2013), 73, 75.

  52. 52.

    D. Evans (2003), 325-354.

  53. 53.

    In the US, although there are three CMOs which grant licenses for the public performance right for the musical works, each of them manages a special repertoire.

  54. 54.

    In order to minimize the transaction costs, the “blanket licenses” found a basis for justification after a years-long dispute between the American collecting society ASCAP and commercial users CBS (Columbia Broadcasting System); see NN (1978), Note CBS v. ASCAP, 783-803; G. Clark (1980), 741-750.

  55. 55.

    D. Evans (2003), 355-356; J. Drexl, S. Nérisson, F. Trumpke, R.M. Hilty (2013), 325-327; J. Drexl (2013), 11, 81; E. Arezzo (2015), 548-549.

  56. 56.

    D. Evans (2009), 355.

  57. 57.

    Regulation 316/214 of 21 March 2014 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to categories of technology transfer agreements, OJ L93/17.

  58. 58.

    Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, issued by the U.S. DOJ and the Federal Trade Commission, 6 April 1995.

  59. 59.

    See CJEU, Case C-52/07 Kanal 5 and TV 4 v. STIM [2008] ECR I-9275, para. 40: “However, it is conceivable that, in certain circumstances, the application of such a remuneration model may amount to an abuse, in particular when another method exists which enables the use of those works and the audience to be identified and quantified more precisely and that method is capable of achieving the same legitimate aim, which is the protection of the interests of composers and music editors, without however leading to a disproportionate increase in the costs incurred for the management of the contracts and the supervision of the use of musical works protected by copyright.” See J. Schovsbo (2012), 185-187.

  60. 60.

    In the US, after the case CBS v. ASCAP, 620 F.2d 930, 934 (2d Cir. 1980), some scholars have noted the relationship between technical development and management conditions and believe that “blanket licensing is maintained for only so long as is necessary for the minimization of transaction costs”; see NN (1978), Note CBS v. ASCAP, 802.

  61. 61.

    N. Dunne (2015), 43-44.

  62. 62.

    Recital 49 of Directive 2014/26/EU (supra n. 3).

  63. 63.

    Article 3 of Directive 2014/26/EU (supra n. 3).

  64. 64.

    A. Schierholz (2010), 1154-1155.

  65. 65.

    Recital 23-24 of Directive 2014/26/EU (supra n. 3).

  66. 66.

    W. Nordemann (1992), 584-589.

  67. 67.

    J. Fujitani (1984), 135.

  68. 68.

    Recital 49 of Directive 2014/26/EU (supra n. 3).

  69. 69.

    R. Stewart (1983), 1567-1569; H. Hovenkamp (2005), 229-230.

  70. 70.

    For more detail on this subject: J. Drexl, S. Nérisson, F. Trumpke, R.M. Hilty (2013), 332-334; J. Drexl (2014), 484-486.

  71. 71.

    M. Hellwig (2009), 15, 212; D. Geradin, R. O’Donoghue (2005), 412; M. Cave, P. Crowther (2005), 487; N. Dunne (2015), 33.

  72. 72.

    M. Lemley (2004), 129; C. Kolstand, T. Ulen, G. Johnson (1990), 888.

  73. 73.

    See—regarding disputes between right holders and CMOs—e.g. CJEU, Case 127/73 BRT v. SABAM [1974] ECR 313; Case IV/29.971—GEMA-Satzung [1981] 82/204/EWG; M. Lichtenegger (2014), 104; regarding disputes between users and CMOs, CJEU, Case C-52/07 Kanal 5 and TV 4 [2008] ECR I-9275 (supra n. 59); Case C-395/87 Ministère public v. Jean-Louis Tournier [1989] ECR I-2521; see also M. Lichtenegger (2014), 109-110.

  74. 74.

    CJEU, Case 78/70 Deutsche Grammophon v. Metro [1971] ECR 487; Case 127/73 BRT v. SABAM [1974] ECR 313; Cases 55/80 and 57/80 Musikvertrieb Membran GmbH v. GEMA [1981] ECR 147; Case 7/82 GVL v. Commission [1983] ECR 483 (supra n. 7). As to U.S. cases see U.S. v. BMI, 1940-43 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 56, 096, 381 (E.D.Wisc.1941); U.S. v. ASCAP, 1940-43 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 56,104, 402 (S.D.N.Y.1941); for their latest amended Consent Decrees see U.S. v. BMI, 1996-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 71, 379 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 18, 1994); U.S. v. ASCAP, 2001-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) paras. 73, 474 (S.D.N.Y. June 11, 2001) (supra n. 8).

  75. 75.

    Accordingly it has been suggested for the US, for instance, to introduce ex ante regulation in the field of collective management; see J. Fujitani (1984), 135; D. Gervais (2011), 610-613; G. Lunney (2010), 333-334; NN (1978), Note CBS v. ASCAP, 802; G. Clark (1980), 749.

  76. 76.

    N. Dunne (2015), 46.

References

  • Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, Issued by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission April 6, 1995: available at: www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.htm

  • Arezzo, E. (2015), Competition and Intellectual Property Protection in the Market for the Provision of Multi-Territorial Licensing of Online Rights in Musical Works – Lights and Shadows of the New European Directive, IIC, 534-565

    Google Scholar 

  • ASCAP Consent Decree: Second Amended Final Judgment entered in United States v. ASCAP (S.D.N.Y. 2001), available at: www.justice.gov/atr/cases/f6300/6396.htm

  • Becker, J. (2008), Verwertungsgesellschaften als Träger öffentlicher und privater Aufgaben, in: R. Kreile, J. Becker, K. Riesenhuber (Eds.), Recht und Praxis der GEMA, Handbuch und Kommentar, 33-43, De Gruyter

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S., Kirby, S., Salop, S. (1992), An Economic Analysis of Copyright Collectives, Virginia Law Rev., 383-411

    Google Scholar 

  • BT-Drucksache VI/ 271(1962): Entwurf eines Gesetzes über Verwertungsgesellschaften auf dem Gebiet des Urheberrechts (Verwertungsgesellschaftengesetz), available at: dipbt.bundestag.de/doc/btd/04/002/0400271.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  • Cave, M., Crowther, P. (2005), Pre-emptive Competition Policy Meets Regulatory Antitrust, ECLR, 481-490, Sweet and Maxwell

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (1980), Blanket Licensing: The Clash Between Copyright Protection and the Sherman Act, 729-750, The Notre Dame Lawyer

    Google Scholar 

  • Commission Recommendation of 18 May 2005 on collective cross-border management of copyright and related rights for legitimate online music services, available at: eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv:OJ.L_.2005.276.01.0054.01.ENG

  • Dietz, A. (1978), Copyright Law in the European Community, 19-21, 212-241, Sijthoff & Noordhoff

    Google Scholar 

  • Drexl, J. (2007), Competition in the Field of Collective Management: Preferring ‘Creative Competition’ to Allocative Efficiency in European Copyright Law, in: P. Torremans (Eds.), Copyright Law. A Handbook of Contemporary Research, 255-282, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Drexl, J. (2013), Copyright, Competition and Development (Report to the World Intellectual Property Organization), 1-284, available at: http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/ip-competition/en/studies/copyright_competition_development.pdf

  • Drexl, J. (2014), Collective Management of Copyrights and the EU Principle of Free Movement of Services after the OSA Judgment – In Favour of a More Balanced Approach, in: K. Purnhagen, P. Rott (Eds.), Varieties of European Economic Law and Regulation – Liber Amicorum for Hans Micklitz, 459-487, Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Drexl, J., Nérisson, S., Trumpke, F., Hilty, R.M. (2013), Comments of the Max Planck Institute for Intellectual Property and Competition Law on the Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on Collective Management of Copyright and Related Rights and Multi-Territorial Licensing of Rights in Musical Works for Online Uses in the Internal Market COM (2012) 372, IIC, 322-350

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, N. (2015), Competition Law and Economic Regulation, Cambridge University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. (2007), Antitrust consent decrees in theory and practice, 2007, 1-14, AEI Press

    Google Scholar 

  • European Affairs (2006), The Collective Management of Rights in Europe The Quest for Efficiency, available at: www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2004_2009/documents/dv/study-collective-management-rights-/study-collective-management-rights-en.pdf

  • Evans, D. (2003), The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Platform Markets, Yale J. on Reg. 2003, 325-381

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. (2009), Two-Sided Market Definition, in: ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Market Definition in Antitrust: Theory and Case Studies, Forthcoming, Global Econ., available at: SSRN: ssrn.com/abstract=1396751

  • Fujitani, J. (1984), Controlling the Market Power of Performing Rights Societies: An Administrative Substitute for Antitrust Regulation, California Law Rev., 103-137

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, D. (1994), The Transformation of European Community Competition Law, Harvard Int. Law, 97-147

    Google Scholar 

  • Geradin, D., O’Donoghue, R. (2005), The concurrent application of competition law and regulation: the case of margin squeeze abuses in the telecommunications sector, J. Comp. Law & Econ., 355-425

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais, D. (2010), Collective Management of Copyright: Theory and Practice in the Digital Age, in Collective Management of Copyright and Related Rights, 1-28, Kluwer Law International

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais, D. (2011), Keynote: The Landscape of Collective Management Schemes, Columbia J. of Law & the Arts, 591-617

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilliéron, P. (2006), Collecting Societies and the Digital Environment, IIC, 939-969

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G., Schmidt-Bischoffshausen, A. (2007), Ökonomische Funktionen von Verwertungsgesellschaften – Kollektive Wahrnehmung im Lichte von Transaktionskosten- und Informationsökonomik, GRUR Int., 461-481

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. (1998), The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets, Harvard Law Rev., 621-688

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, M. (2009), Competition Policy and Sector-Specific Regulation for Network Industries, in: V. Xavier (Ed.), Competition Policy in the EU, 203-235, Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Herschel, W. (1967), Staatsentlastende Artigkeit der Verwertungsgesellschaften, UFITA Bd. 1967, 22-32

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R.M. (2010), Kollektive Rechtewahrnehmung und Vergütungsregelungen: Harmonisierungsbedarf und -möglichkeiten, in: M. Leistner (Eds.), Europäische Perspektiven des Geistigen Eigentums, 123-166, Mohr Siebeck

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R.M. (2012), Individual, Multiple and Collective Ownership – What Impact on Competition?, in: J. Rosén (Eds.), Individualism and Collectivization in Intellectual Property Law, 3-44, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R.M., Nérisson, S. (2013), Collective Copyright Management: The European Experience, in: R. Towse, C. Handke (Eds.): Handbook of the Digital Creative Economy, 222-234, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Hovenkamp, H. (2005), The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution, Harvard University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, A. (2005), The Potential Demise of Another Natural Monopoly: Rethinking the Collective Administration of Performing Rights, J. Comp. Law & Econ., 541-593

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzenberger, P., Nérisson, S. (2011), Kulturförderung, Solidarität und Verteilungsgerechtigkeit in Recht und Praxis urheberrechtlicher Verwertungsgesellschaften, GRUR Int., 283-295

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad, C., Ulen, T., Johnson, G. (1990), Ex Post Liability for Harm vs. Ex Ante Safety Regulation: Substitutes or Complements?, American Econ. Rev, 888-901

    Google Scholar 

  • Kretschmer, M. (2002), The Failure of Property Rules in Collective Administration: Rethinking Copyright Societies as Regulatory Instruments, European Intellectual Prop. Rev., 126-137

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamping, M. (2015), Refusal to License as an Abuse of Market Dominance – From Commercial Solvents to Microsoft, in: R.M. Hilty, K.-C. Liu (Eds.), Compulsory Licensing, Practical Experiences and Ways Forward, 121-145, Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley, M. (2004), Ex Ante versus Ex Post Justification for Intellectual Property, Univ. of Chicago Law Rev., 129-149

    Google Scholar 

  • von Lewinski, S. (2005), Gedanken zur kollektiven Rechtewahrnehmung, in: A. Ohly, T. Bodewig, T. Dreier, H.-P. Götting, M. Haedicke, M. Lehmann (Eds.): Perspektiven des Geistigen Eigentums und Wettbewerbsrechts, 401- 412, C.H. Beck

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenegger, M. (2014), Verwertungsgesellschaften, Kartellverbot und Neue Medien, Mohr Siebeck

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindstrom, T., Tighe, K. (1974), Antitrust Consent Decrees, Rochester

    Google Scholar 

  • Lunney, G. (2010), Copyright Collectives and Collecting Societies: The United States Experience, in Collective Management of Copyright and Related Rights, 311-345, Kluwer Law International

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges, R. (1996), Contracting into Liability Rules: Intellectual Property Rights and Collective Rights Organizations, California Law Rev., 1293-1393

    Google Scholar 

  • NN (1978), Note CBS v. ASCAP: Performing Rights Societies and the Per Se Rule, Yale Law J. 1978, 783-803

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordemann, W. (1992), Mängel der Staatsaufsicht über die deutschen Verwertungsgesellschaften?, GRUR, 584-589

    Google Scholar 

  • Peifer, K.-N. (2015), Die Zukunft der kollektiven Rechtewahrnehmung, GRUR, 27-35

    Google Scholar 

  • Podszun, R. (2014), Die Kontrolle der Verwertungsgesellschaften, in: M. Grünberger, S. Leible (Eds.): Die Kollision von Urheberrecht und Nutzerverhalten im Informationszeitalter, 173-210, Mohr Siebeck

    Google Scholar 

  • Searle, N., White, G. (2013), Business models, in: R. Towse, C. Handke (Eds.): Handbook of the Digital Creative Economy, 45-56, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Schierholz, A. (2010), Collective Rights Management in Europe – Practice and Legal Framework, in: M.M. Walter, S. von Lewinski (Eds.), European copyright law. A commentary, 1145-1190, Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Schovsbo, J. (2012), The necessity to collectivize copyright – and dangers thereof, in: J. Rosén (Eds.), Individualism and Collectiveness in Intellectual Property Law, 167-191, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Snow, A., Watt, R. (2005), Risk Sharing and the Distribution of Copyright Collective Income, in: L. Takeyama, W. Gordon, R. Towse (Eds.), Developments in the Economics of Copyright: Research and Analysis, 23-36, Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, R. (1983), Regulation in a Liberal State: The Role of Non-Commodity Values, Yale Law J., 1537-1590

    Google Scholar 

  • The EU Commission notice on the definition of relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law (1997), OJ No. C 273

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, K., Joseph, E., John, M. (2005), Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, MIT press

    Google Scholar 

  • Vázquez-Lopez, V. (2010), Collective and individual exercise of copyright in the digital environment: An international perspective focused on development, GRUR Int., 689-695

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Reto M. Hilty .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hilty, R.M., Li, T. (2017). Control Mechanisms for CRM Systems and Competition Law. In: Liu, KC., Hilty, R. (eds) Remuneration of Copyright Owners. MPI Studies on Intellectual Property and Competition Law, vol 27. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-53809-8_9

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-53809-8_9

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-662-53808-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-53809-8

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics