Skip to main content
  • 27 Accesses

Abstract

The main conclusion suggested by this study is that both the structure — that is the regional distribution, commodity composition and balancing of payments — and the modus operandi of international trade have been radically altered in the last thirty years.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Except for the period embracing the First World War and the early twenties» when Great Britain went off the Gold Standard.

    Google Scholar 

  2. William Y. Elliott, et al, The Political Economy of American Foreign Policy, (New York: Henry Holt and Co., 1955), p. 207. The following quotation offers an interesting evaluation of Bretton Woods:

    Google Scholar 

  3. This statement should be qualified with respect to the Sterling Area to apply to intra-imports. The rise in the share of intra-exports to total bloc exports had been quite appreciable in the thirties, and remained stable in the postwar period (See Table 48). Furthermore the tendency towards trade region-alization within the Sterling Bloc appeared to have come to an end by 1954 (See Chapter V).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Based on Tables 40, 48, and 55.

    Google Scholar 

  5. The ratio of intratrade to total free world trade kept on increasing slightly between 1954 and 1956 within both the Dollar Area and the Continental O. E. E. C. Bloc, but declined sharply within the Sterling Area.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Diagrams 1 and 2 in Chapter III.

    Google Scholar 

  7. The above-mentioned factors appear to have played a much more important part in furthering trade within the blocs than price considerations as such. At least one study showed that the correlation between unit value of exports and the volume of exports of manufactures from industrial Western Europe and the U. S. was not very high in the postwar period. (See J. M. Fleming and S. C. Tsiang, “Changes in Competitive Strength and Export Shares of Major Industrial Countries,” International Monetary Fund, Staff Papers; August, 1956).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Trimn, op. cit., p. 246. The same author concludes after a thorough analysis of the effects of monetary and commercial agreements in Western Europe after the end of World War II that: Regional agreements and organizations have (nevertheless) demonstrated their ability to solve pressing conflicts and to achieve intimate, even though incomplete, integration of economic policies among countries, recognizing at the same time that: Looser forms of coordination on a world-wide scale remain both feasible and necessary as a framework for national or regional decisions and policies giving rise to conflicts of interest, real or imagined, which cannot be arbitrated on the regional level. (Ibid., p. 259.)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Rockefeller Report on U. S. International Economic Policy, Foreign Economic Policy for the Twentieth Century, Special Studies Project Report III, (New York, Doubleday and Co., 1958), p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Ibid., pp. 29–30. It is interesting to note that the Rockefeller Report devoted a whole chapter to an outline of the type of regional structure, including a common market and an inter-American payments union, which could be set up for the Western Hemisphere as a whole (See Chapter V, pp. 61–68).

    Google Scholar 

  11. See Jacob Viner, The Customs Union Issue, (New York: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1950).

    Google Scholar 

  12. These criteria are based on Viner, op. cit., pp. 41–54; James E. Meade, The Theory of Customs Union, (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1955), pp. 107–115, and Elliott, op. cit., pp. 236–237. It should be noted for completeness sake, that these criteria refer in a strict sense to a customs union. However, they do not seem greatly impaired when applied to “blocs.”

    Google Scholar 

  13. Elliott, op. cit., p. 237.

    Google Scholar 

  14. The Dollar Bloc does not present enough characteristics of a union to warrant a critical appraisal of the desirability of the regionalization tendency which it has been undergoing. Nevertheless it can be argued that this trend is desirable to the extent that it is caused by changes in the structure of the dollar countries economies.

    Google Scholar 

  15. See Chapter IV, pp. 125–126.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Internal tariffs and quotas are to be gradually eliminated over a transitional period of 12 to 15 years. The common tariff vis-à-vis the outside world will eventually be based, with a few exceptions, on the arithmetic averages of the present ad valorem tariff of the member states. The Treaty of Rome has a number of special provisions for agricultural policies which could interfere with the freeing of intratrade in agricultural commodities.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Scitovsky believes on the basis of a careful theoretical analysis of the question that the greatest impact of future European integration will be on the methods of production and investment rather than on an international reallocation of output. His contention is that the scope for reallocation within many national industries is so large that such reallocation would, not only precede but also, often take the place of reallocation between national industries. (See Tibor Scitovsky, Economic Theory and Western European Integration, (London, Allen and Unwin, 1958), pp. 39–40.

    Google Scholar 

  18. See, for instance, 1) J. Viner’s statement: “I would argue that in general, for a European customs union, or a Western European customs union, whether it embraced England or not, there would be a strong presumption that it would be to the marked advantage of the world as a whole.” Hearings, op. cit., p. 610; 2) Franz Gehrels and Bruce F. Johnston, “The Economic Gains of European Integration,” The Journal of Political Economy, (August, 1955), pp. 291–292; 3) F. V. Meyer, “Complementarity and the Lowering of Tariffs,” American Economic Review, (June, 1956), pp. 334–335; 4) Tibor Scitovs-ky, op. cit., pp. 132–135.

    Google Scholar 

  19. In the case of semi-manufactures if 10 per cent ad valorem is taken as the dividing line between high and low tariffs, less than one tenth of all tariff incidences fall above this line in the Benelux countries as compared with more than 70 per cent in France and Italy, and about 50 per cent in Western Germany. In the finished-goods sector taking 20 per cent ad valorem as the borderline about 10 per cent of all tariff incidences fall above this line in Benelux as opposed to about two-thirds in Italy and half of all incidences in France. (For further detail see U. N., Economic Survey of Europe, 1956, Ch. IV, pp. 14–15.)

    Google Scholar 

  20. This point has been emphasized in a few recent publications. See particularly: 1) G. A. T. T., Trends in International Trade, A Report by a Panel of Experts (Campos, Haberler, Meade, Tinbergen), Geneva, 1958, pp. 119–122, and 2) U. N., Economic Survey of Europe 1957, Ch. V, pp. 17–19.

    Google Scholar 

  21. The total value of imports of foodstuffs and raw materials into North America from Dollar Latin America is expected to rise from 2.4 billion dollars in 1954–1956 (average) to 4.7 billion dollars in 1975, whereas total imports from all areas (excluding trade between Canada and the U. S.) are anticipated to increase from 7.2 billion dollars to 12.2 billion dollars over the same period. (See U. N. Economic Survey of Europe 1957, Chapter V, p. 12, Table 7.)

    Google Scholar 

  22. As previously mentioned the Rockefeller Report in fact analyzed the lines along which such a regional trading and payments sphere could be formed (See Rockefeller Report, op. cit., Chapter V).

    Google Scholar 

  23. See Table 48. In this respect it seems true, as Triffin points out, that Two world wars have sapped the financial and economic strength of the United Kingdom to such an extent as to cast growing doubts everywhere about its ability to resume its traditional position as the sole core and support of the enormous superstructure erected in former days, upon sterling trade and sterling financing (Triflin, op. cit., p. 279).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1959 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Thorbecke, E. (1959). Economic Regionalism Critical Evaluation and Future Prospects. In: The Tendency towards Regionalization in International Trade 1928–1956. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-1053-0_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-1053-0_7

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-015-0424-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-015-1053-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics