Skip to main content

The Sensory Order Revisited

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Evolving Norms

Part of the book series: Palgrave Advances in Behavioral Economics ((PABE))

  • 486 Accesses

Abstract

In The Sensory Order (1952), Hayek provided a theory of the process by which the mind perceives the world around it. The sensory order is a classification that takes place via a network of impulse connections. The essence of Hayek’s attempt in theoretical psychology is to show how a structure can be formed which discriminates between different physical stimuli and generates the sensory order that we actually experience. The sensory order is even an incomplete and imperfect representation of the physical world. The subjectivity of individual knowledge finds its foundation in the construction of the mind. The brain is an adaptive system interacting with and adapting to its environment by performing a multi-level classification on the stimuli it receives from the environment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Hayek’s contribution to cognitive theory has received explicit recognition from neuroscientists (Edelman 1989 ; Fuster 2005 ).

  2. 2.

    Some researchers (Butos and Koppl 1993 ; Caldwell 2000 , 2004 ; Horwitz 2000 ; Rizzello 1999 ; Streit 1993 ; Teraji 2014 ) argue that Hayek’s cognitive theory spilled over to his later work on political and social theory.

  3. 3.

    In the early 1950s, Hayek was led to investigate an ever-broadening range of fields, from biology and evolutionary theory, to systems theory, to cybernetics and theories of communication, all of which offered explanations of the principles underlying the complex phenomena with which they dealt (Caldwell 2000 ).

  4. 4.

    According to Fleetwood ( 1995 ), prior to 1936 Hayek might be defined as a positivist; between 1936 and 1960 he adopts a synthesis of subjective idealist epistemology and empirical realist ontology. After 1960 he endorses a position that Fleetwood ( 1995 ) calls quasi-critical realist or transcendental realist.

  5. 5.

    It is generally agreed that the 1871 publication of Principles of Economics , by Carl Menger, gave birth to the Austrian school. Menger’s primary contributions in economics include the subjective theory of value, the discovery of the law of marginal utility, the theory of the spontaneous emergence of institutions, and the conception of the production process as a series of successive temporal stages. Despite his contributions to marginal analysis and to value theory based upon the concept of utility, Menger had a different methodological approach than the other economists who contributed to the marginal revolution. For instance, he rejected the use of mathematization on the grounds that economic theory is not studying ‘interdependencies’ but ‘essences’.

  6. 6.

    According to Vaughn ( 1994 ), the Austrians, most fundamentally, agree that economics should make the world intelligible in terms of human action. The first implication is that economics should subscribe to methodological individualism. The second is that economics must explain human action as the individuals’ responses to their subjective interpretations of their internal and external environment.

  7. 7.

    From a contemporary Austrian perspective, “knowledge is a multifaceted, heterogenous, disaggregated, often private or tacit and imperfect phenomenon” (Vaughn 1994 , p. 4).

  8. 8.

    This is illustrated by Hayek’s own experience: “I have always regarded myself as a living refutation of the contention that all thinking takes place in word or generally in language. I am as certain as I can be that I have often been aware of having the answer to a problem—of ‘seeing’ it before me, long before I could express it in words. Indeed, a sort of visual imagination, of symbolic abstract patterns rather than representational pictures, probably played a bigger role in my mental processes than words” (Hayek 1994 , pp. 134–135).

  9. 9.

    According to Polanyi ( 1969 ), “tacit knowing is the fundamental power of the mind, which creates explicit knowledge, lends meaning to it and controls its use” (Polanyi 1969 , p. 156).

  10. 10.

    Mises is responsible fort the Austrian school’s most vital practical contributions: the theory of the impossibility of socialism, the theory of economic cycles, the theory of entrepreneurship, the criticism of interventionism, and the systematization of the Austrian methodology.

  11. 11.

    See Zwirn ( 2009 ) for Mises’s attempt to establish an epistemological foundation for social sciences.

  12. 12.

    In Hodgson ( 2003 , p. 164), “[h]abits themselves are formed through repetition of action and thought. They are influenced by prior activity and have durable self-sustaining qualities. Through their habits, individuals carry the marks of their own unique history.”

  13. 13.

    Crawford and Ostrom ( 1995 ) develop the grammar of institutions and propose that all institutional statements are coded using a syntax. According to them, the general syntax of the grammar of institutions contains five components: ‘Attributes [A],’ ‘Deontic [D],’ ‘Aim [I],’ ‘Conditions [C],’ and ‘Or else [O].’ Rules include all five components (ADICO), norms have four components (ADIC), and shared strategies have only three components (AIC).

  14. 14.

    Rizzo ( 2013 , pp. 50–51) lists highly interrelated 8 themes about Austrian economics: (1) the subjective (yet socially embedded) quality of human decision making; (2) the individual’s perception of the passage of time; (3) the radical uncertainty of expectations; (4) the decentralization of explicit and tacit knowledge in society; (5) the dynamic market processes generated by individual action; (6) the function of the price system in transmitting knowledge; (7) the supplementary role of cultural norms and other cultural products (institutions) in conveying knowledge; and (8) the spontaneous evolution of social institutions.

  15. 15.

    According to Lachmann, the main task of social theory is to explain observable phenomena by reducing them to the individual plans that typically give rise to them.

Bibliography

  • Boettke, P. & Prychitko, D. (Eds.) (1994). The market process: Essays in contemporary austrian economics. Aldershot: E. Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butos, W. N. & Koppl, R. G. (1993). Hayekian expectations: Theory and empirical applications. Constitutional Political Economy, 4, 303–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2000). The emergence of Hayek’s ideas on cultural evolution. Review of Austrian Economics, 13, 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2004). Hayek’s challenge: An intellectual biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, S. & Ostrom, E. (1995). A grammar of institutions. American Political Science Review, 89, 582–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. T. & North, D. C. (1994). Shared mental models: Ideologies and institutions. Kyklos, 47, 3–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, G. M. (1989). The remembered present: A biological theory of consciousness. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleetwood, S. (1995). Hayek’s political economy: The socio-economics of order. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuster, J. M. (2005). Cortex and mind; Unifying cognition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967). Studies in philosophy, politics, and economics. London & Henley: Routledge & Kagan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. ([1952] 1979). The counter-revolution of science, 2nd ed. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press. Original Work Published 1952.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 1, Rules and order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1978). New studies in philosophy, politics, economics and the history of ideas. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1979). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 3, The political order of a free people. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1994). Hayek on Hayek: An autobiographical dialogue. In S. Kresge & L. Wenar (Eds.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1988). The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2014). The collected works of F. A. Hayek, Vol. 15, The markets and other orders. In B. Caldwell (Ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (1997). The ubiquity of habits and rules. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21, 663–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2003). The hidden persuaders: Institutions and individuals in economic theory. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27, 159–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2006). What are institutions? Journal of Economic Issues, 40, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. (2000). From The Sensory Order to the liberal order: Hayek’s non-rationalist liberalism. Review of Austrian Economics, 13, 23–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1970). The legacy of Max Weber. London: Heinnemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1976). From Mises to Shackle: An essay on Austrian economics and the Kaleidic society. Journal of Economic Literature, 14, 54–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1986). The market as an economic process. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (2015). Process, order and stability in Veblen. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39, 993–1030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantzavinos, C., North, D. C., & Sharid, S. (2004). Learning, institutions, and economic performance. Perspectives on Politics, 2, 75–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McQuade, T. & Butos, W. (2005). The sensory order and other adaptive classifying systems. Journal of Bioeconomics, 7, 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1966). Human action, a treatise on economics. Chicago: Henry Regnery. Original Work Published 1949.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P. Jr., & Rizzo, M. J. (1996). The economics of time and ignorance, 2nd ed. London: Routlege.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, M. (1969). Knowing and being: Essays by Michael Polanyi. M. Grene (Ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzello, S. (1999). The economics of the mind. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzo, M. J. (2013). Foundations of The Economics of Time and Ignorance. Review of Austrian Economics, 26, 45–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1959). Theories of decision-making in economics and behavioral science. American Economic Review, 49, 253–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Streit, M. E. (1993). Cognition, competition, and catallaxy: In memory of Friedrich August von Hayek. Constitutional Political Economy, 4, 223–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teraji, S. (2014). On cognition and cultural evolution. Mind and Society, 13, 167–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science, 211, 453–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaughn, K. I. (1994). Austrian economics in America: The migration of a tradition. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class: An economic study of institutions. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenzel, N. (2010). From contract to mental models: Constitutional culture as a fact of the social science. Review of Austrian Economics, 23, 55–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zwirn, G. (2009). Ludwig von Mieses on the epistemological foundation for social sciences reconstructed. Review of Austrian Economics, 22, 81–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

Âİ 2016 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Teraji, S. (2016). The Sensory Order Revisited. In: Evolving Norms. Palgrave Advances in Behavioral Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-50247-6_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-50247-6_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, New York

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-50246-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-50247-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics