Skip to main content

Perspectives, Arguments and the Structure

  • Chapter
The Political Economy of Korea
  • 233 Accesses

Abstract

A classic case of historical economic backwardness, the Korean peninsula faced external subjugation and internal stagnation for most of the second millennium. Invasions by the Khitans (10th and 11th century), Mongols (1231–59), Manchus (1627–36) and Japanese (1592–98) made Korea (hereafter refers to Korea prior to division as well as to South Korea, or the Republic of Korea) seek refuge in the Chinese ‘tributary system.’ However, the nineteenth-century rise of industrialism in Europe and the relative decline in China’s power brought intense Western imperialist pressure on Korea to force open its ports for international trade and commerce. General Sherman incident in 1876, Korean-American War of 1871 and Japanese raids to Busan in 1876 created hostility between Koreans and foreigners. These bitter historical experiences with outside powers caused Korea to harbor deep-seated distrust toward foreigners, culminating in an explicit policy of self-isolation, earning it the designation, ‘Hermit Kingdom.’ 1 The far-reaching external changes unfolding at the turn of the 20th century brought enormous pressure on Korea to adapt to new demands from the competing foreign interests. Unprepared to react effectively, Korea (under the Chinese tributary system, Sadae Chui) showed unwillingness to adjust to the structurally changed situation around the peninsula and, consequently, became the victim of colonialism, World War II and a subsequent painful national division.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. William Elliot Griffis’s book (1882) Corea: The Hermit Nation, is the first documented source that used the term ‘Hermit Kingdom.’ Many Koreans also use this term to refer to pre-modern Korea.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The term Yangban finds its origin in the civil service examination conducted under Munkwa (civilian) and Mukwa (military) categories during the Koryo Dynasty (935–1392). However, during the Joseon Dynasty the entire landholding class was known as Yangbans, who for obvious reasons controlled various privileges offered by the state, including the exclusive right to give civil service exams, large tracts of land and other stipends, etc. In the absence of any socio-political contest, the Yangban-dominated status quo continued even during the colonial period. Only comprehensive land reforms post-independence were able to finally end Yangban domination. For further details about this tiny aristocracy, see Martina Deuchler (1995) The Confucian Transformation of Korea: A Study of Society and Ideology, Harvard-Yenching Institute Monograph Series, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center;

    Google Scholar 

  3. Young-Chan Ro (1989) The Korean Neo-Confucianism of Yi Yulgok, Suny Series in Philosophy, Albany, N.Y.: State University of New York Press;

    Google Scholar 

  4. Carter J. Eckert, Ki-Baik Lee, Young Lew, Michael Robinson and Edward W. Wagner (1991) Korea Old and New: A History, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Korea Institute;

    Google Scholar 

  5. Ki-Baik Lee, Edward J. Schultz and Edward W. Wagner (trans.) (2005) A New History of Korea, Harvard-Yenching Institute Publications: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  6. In the 1960s, Korea’s real GDP registered an average 9 percent growth rate; in the 1970s, it moved to 9.3 percent and touched 10 percent in the 1980s. Similarly, Korea’s industrial transformation was equally remarkable, as by 1996 Korea became the world’s No. 1 manufacturer of memory chips, the No. 2 shipbuilder, No. 3 supplier of semiconductors, No. 4 in electronics and No. 5 in automobiles. For details see, Alice H. Amsden (1992) Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, New York: Oxford University Press;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  7. John Lie (1998) Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  8. Jung-en Woo (1991) Race to Swift: State and Finance in the Korean Industrialization, New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  9. The quantum leap from the ‘feudal agrarian economy’ with per capita GNI US$60 in 1960 to one of the ‘advanced industrialized economies’ crossing per capita GNI US$11,385 in 1996 and touching US$24,000 in 2013 has been achieved within a generation. For the details of this remarkable transformation, see L. Jones and I. SaKong (1980) Government, Business, and Entrepreneurship in Economic Development: The Korean Case, Studies in the Modernization of Korea: 1945–75, Harvard East Asian monographs, vol. 91, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  10. I. SaKong (1993) Korea in the World Economy, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics;

    Google Scholar 

  11. B. N. Song (1997) The Rise of the Korean Economy, 2nd edn., New York: Oxford University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  12. H. K. Lee (1996) The Korean Economy: Perspectives for the Twenty-First Century, Suny Series in Korean Studies, Albany, N.Y.: State University of New York Press;

    Google Scholar 

  13. C. F. Bergsten and I. Choe, (eds) (2003) Korean Diaspora in the World Economy, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics;

    Google Scholar 

  14. J. Kim (2002) The South Korean Economy: Towards a New Explanation of an Economic Miracle, Aldershot, Hampshire: Ashgate Publishing Co.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Books carrying such titles provided convincing explanations regarding Korea’s first successful transition from the agrarian to the industrial era. For details, see Alice H. Amsden (1992) Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, New York: Oxford University Press;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  16. John Lie (1998) Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Literature on the Korean financial crisis is divided into two perspectives; first, a systemic crisis perspective that blames macroeconomic imbalances, moral hazard in banking and external shocks as a major cause of the crisis; second, a financial liberalization and structural weaknesses perspective that cites unproductive credit in the banking system, financial liberalization that created scope for currency and maturity mismatches, and a self-fulfilling loss of market confidence, manifested in the refusal of foreign lenders to roll over short-term loans to banks, forcing illiquid borrowers into bankruptcy. For further details regarding literature on the financial crisis, see G. G. Kaufman, T. H. Krueger, W. C. Hunter (1999) The Asian Financial Crisis: Origins, Implications and Solutions, New York: Springer;

    Google Scholar 

  18. J. D. Sachs and S. Radelet (1998) ‘The East Asian Financial Crisis: Diagnosis, Remedies, Prospects,’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1: 1–74;

    Google Scholar 

  19. Helen Hughes (1999) ‘Crony Capitalism and the East Asian Currency Financial “Crises”,’ Policy, 15(3): 3–9;

    Google Scholar 

  20. Ha-Joon Chang, Hong Jae Park, Chul Gyue Yoo (1998) ‘Interpreting Korean Crisis: Financial Liberalization, Industrial Policy and Corporate Governance,’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 22(6): 735–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. The prime indicator of corporate control is a nation’s stock market, which in the case of Korea permitted only 13 percent foreign ownership in 1996 and increased to 50 percent in 1997. More specifically, 58.1 percent Samsung Electronics, 55.3 percent Hyundai Motors, and 70.1 percent POSCO equity moved to foreign hands. Similarly, foreign ownership in the Korean banking sector in mid-2005 was 74 percent for the Korea Exchange Bank, 100 percent for Korea-America Bank, owned by Citibank, 100 percent for Korea First Bank, owned by Standard Chartered, 76 percent for Hana, 84 percent for Kookmin, and 63 percent for Shinhan Bank. For further analysis on this matter, see J. Crotty and K. Lee (2005) ‘The Effects of Neoliberal “Reform” on the Post-Crisis Korean Economy,’ PERI Working Paper Series, 111: 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  22. ‘People’s Committee’ has been referred to as local self-governing body that was leaning left but was open to other ideologies as well. In the wake of liberation, these committees sprang up on the entire peninsula, involved in restoring basic services after the sudden departure of the Japanese colonial government; however their close proximity to the left movement was seen with a degree of skepticism by the U.S. government, which finally acted firmly to demolish them. For details about these committees, see Martin Hart-Landsberg (1998) Korea: Division, Reunification, and U.S. Foreign Policy, New York: Monthly Review Press;

    Google Scholar 

  23. G. Handerson (1968) Korea: The Politics of Vortex, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  24. For details of the critique provided to the Chaebol-dominated political economy, see Seung-Rok Park and Ky-Hyang Yuhn (2012), ‘Has the Korean Model of Chaebol Succeeded?’ Journal of Economic Studies 39(2): 260–74; Yuji Akaba, Florian Budde and Jungkiu Choi (1998) ‘Restructuring South Korea’s Chaebol,’ McKinsey Quarterly, (4): 68–79;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Un-chan Chung (2007) Cool Head, Warm Heart, Seoul: Humandom Corp.;

    Google Scholar 

  26. Duck-Koo Chung and Barry Eichengreen (eds) (2004) The Korean Economy beyond the Crisis, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar;

    Google Scholar 

  27. Sunhyuk Kim (2001) Politics of Democratization in Korea: The Role of Civil Society, Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press;

    Google Scholar 

  28. Jang-Sup Shin and Ha-Joon Chang (2003) Restructuring Korea Inc., London & New York: Routledge-Curzon.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  29. Martin Hart-Landsberg (1993) The Rush to Development: Economic Change and Political Struggle in South Korea, New York: Monthly Review Press, 99.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Bruce Cumings (1981) The Origins of the Korean War: Liberation and the Emergence of Separate Regimes, 1945–47, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 10.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Based on Andre Gunder Frank’s (1998) non-Eurocentric analysis and drawing upon Giovanni Arrighi et al. (2003) and Immanuel Wallerstein’s frameworks (2005), an attempt has been made to trace the historical development of East Asia in relation to the transformation of the world system. World system analysis goes beyond nation-state and looks into world system dynamics and regional geo-politics. It examines such processes as incorporation into the world system, regionalization, the Cold War, the Japanese flying geese model, and China’s national reunification project, etc. For details, see Andre Gunder Frank (1998) ReOrient. Berkeley: University of California Press. This study traces the historical development of East Asia in relations to the transformation of the world system.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Giovanni Arrighi, Po-Leung Hui, Ho-Fung Hung and Mark Selden (2003) ‘Historical Capitalism, East and West,’ 259–334 in Giovanni Arrighi et al. (eds) (2003) The Resurgence of East Asia, London & New York: Routledge. This study traces the connection between capitalism in the West and capitalism in the East.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Immanuel Wallerstein (1991) Geopolitics and Geoculture: Essays on the Changing World-System, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  34. For further details about Williamson’s ‘internal organization model,’ see Oliver E. Williamson (1981) ‘The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach,’ American Journal of Sociology, 87(3): 548–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. For details, see Wei-Ming Tu (1988) ‘A Confucian Perspective on the Rise of Industrial East Asia,’ The American Academy of Arts and Sciences Bulletin, 62(1), 32–50;

    Google Scholar 

  36. Hung-Chao Tai, ed., (1989) Confucianism and Economic Development: An Oriental Alternative?, Washington D.C.: The Washington Institute Press;

    Google Scholar 

  37. Lucian W. Pye (1990) ‘The New Asian Capitalism: A Political Portrait,’ in Peter L. Berger and Hsin-Huang Michael Hsiao (eds) (1990) In Search of an East Asian Development Model, New Brunswick, NJ, and London: Transaction Publishers, 81–98;

    Google Scholar 

  38. Marion J. Levy, Jr. (1992) ‘Confucianism and Modernization,’ Society, 29(4), 15–18;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. David Throsby (2001) Economics and Culture, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  40. F. Adams, Gerard and Heidi Vernon (2007) ‘Evaluating the “Asian culture/Asian Success” Hypothesis,’ Journal of Asia-Pacific Business, 8(4), 5–20;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Michael W. Allen, Sik Hung Ng, Ken’ichi Ikeda, Jayum A. Jawan, Anwarul Hasan Sufi, Marc Wilson and Kuo-Shu Yang (2007) ‘Two Decades of Change in Cultural Values and Economic Development in Eight East Asian and Pacific Island Nations,’ Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 38(3), 247–69;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Damien Power, Tobias Schoenherr and Danny Samson (2009) ‘The Cultural Characteristic of Individualism/Collectivism: A Comparative Study of Implications for Investment Operations between Emerging Asian and Industrialized Western Countries,’ Journal of Operations Management, 28, 206–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Korea’s national culture derives core logic from Confucian philosophy that argues for unambiguous authority based on hierarchy. This clarity in authority brought discipline and hard work among the Korean people, which contributed to the economy’s development. For details, see Lee-Jay Cho (1994) ‘Culture, Institutions and Economic Development in East Asia,’ in L. J. Cho and Y. H. Kim (eds) Korea’s Political Economy: An Institutional Perspective, Boulder: Westview Press, 3–41;

    Google Scholar 

  44. Sang-Seek Park (1995) ‘Culture and Development: The Korean Experiment,’ Korea and World Affairs, 19(3), 510–21;

    Google Scholar 

  45. Yoon Hyung Kim (1994) ‘An Introduction to the Korean Model of Political Economy,’ in Lee-Jay Cho and Yoon Hyung Kim (eds) (1994) Korea’s Political Economy: An Institutional Perspective, Boulder: Westview Press, 45–62;

    Google Scholar 

  46. Byung-Nak Song (2003) The Rise of the Korean Economy, Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 56–9;

    Google Scholar 

  47. Bon Ho Koo (1995) ‘Sociocultural Factors in the Industrialisation of Korea,’ in B. H. Koo and D. H. Perkins (eds) (1995) Social Capability and Long-Term Economic Growth, New York: St. Martin’s Press, 181–202;

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  48. Duck Woo Nam (1994) ‘Korean’s Economic Takeoff in Retrospect,’ in S. Y. Kwack (ed.) (1994) The Korean Economy at a Crossroad, London: Praeger, 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  49. D. Kingsbury (2001) South-East Asia: A Political Profile, New York: Oxford University Press, 10–11

    Google Scholar 

  50. For details on colonial modernity in Korea, see Atul Kohli (1994) ‘Where Do High Growth Political Economies Come From? The Japanese Lineage of Korea’s Developmental State,’ World Development, 22(9), 1269–93;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Carter J. Eckert (1991) Offspring of Empire: The Koch’ang Kims and the Colonial Origins of Korean Capitalism, 1876–1945, Seattle: University of Washington Press;

    Google Scholar 

  52. Stephan Haggard, David Kang and Chung-in Moon (1997) ‘Japanese Colonialism and Korean Development: A Critique,’ World Development, 25(6), 867–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Kijun Cho (1973) Hangukjabonjueui Seongripsaron (A Study on the History of Formation of Korean Capitalism). Seoul: Bakyeongsa.

    Google Scholar 

  54. For the role of ‘people’s committees’ in altering political-economic priorities, see Martin Hart-Landsberg (1998) Korea: Division, Reunification, and U.S. Foreign Policy, New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  55. In the post-financial crisis (1997) phase, the NGO sector in Korea expanded rapidly. There exist more than 20,000 NGOs in South Korea (NGO Times, 2000). It is notable that the number of NGOs increased dramatically in the 1990s, as indicated by the fact that more than 56 percent of NGOs were established in the 1990s. More than numbers, the NGO sector in Korea commands more societal trust than other political institutions, including political parties. In 1991 the Citizens’ Coalition for Economic Justice (CCEJ), a Korean NGO, was formed to seek an ethical overhaul of the economic system. For this purpose, CCEJ founded the Korean Economic Justice Institute (KEJI) to evaluate the ethical performance of large Korean corporations. For details, see Soo Joo Sung (2000) ‘Understanding the NGO Revolution in Korea,’ Global Economic Review, 29(4), 3–19;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  56. Euiyoung Kim (2002) ‘Lowering Entry Barrier: The Case of the Deregulation of the Business Interest Association,’ in Jongryn Mo, et al. (eds) (2002) Case Studies on Economic Reform in Korea, Seoul: Oruem (in Korean);

    Google Scholar 

  57. Junki Kim (2000) ‘The Growth of the Non-Government Sector in Korea and Its Relations with the State,’ Global Economic Review, 29(4), 20–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. For details about the April 1960 Student Revolution, see C. I. Eugene Kim and Ke-soo Kim (1964) ‘The April 1960 Korean Student Movement,’ The Western Political Quarterly, 17(1), 83–92; Alan Stone (1974) ‘The Korean Student Revolution: A Political Analysis,’ Occasional Papers on Korea, University of Washington, Center for Korea Studies, (2), 132–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. President Park Chung-Hee ‘traded political rights to economic rights with the United States.’ This careful exchange greatly helped the national bourgeoisie to consolidate. For further details, see Hwang Jong-Sung (1997) ‘Analysis of the Structure of the Korean Political Elite,’ Korea Journal, 37(4), 98–117;

    Google Scholar 

  60. Kyong-Dong Kim (1976) ‘Political Factors in the Formation of the Entrepreneurial Elite in South Korea,’ Asia Survey, 26(5), 465–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Criticism of the state-Chaebol nexus became the core political logic powering progressive thinking; see details David Kang (2002) Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; Soon-il Hong (2001) ‘Cronyism,’ Korea Times.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  62. Korea’s former president, Kim Dae-Jung, promoted the idea of majority participation in the nation’s economic activities, which came to be known as ‘DJnomics.’ For details, see Ministry of Finance and Economy (1999) DJnomics: A New Foundation for the Korean Economy, Korea Development Institute;

    Google Scholar 

  63. Dae-Jung Kim (1985) Mass-Participatory Economy: A Democratic Alternative for Korea, Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, and University Press of America.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Korea has tried to recast its capitalism by linking it to the bottom of the industrial pyramid; however, the role of SMEs in the Korean industrial system is still at the margins. For further details, see Ian Pirie (2008) The Korean Developmental State: From Dirigisme to Neo-Liberalism, London: Routledge;

    Google Scholar 

  65. R. M. Janelli and D. Yim (1995) Making Capitalism: The Social and Cultural Construction of a South Korean Conglomerate, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  66. For the details about cultural-industrial inter-linkages, see J. Howkins (2001), The Creative Economy: How People Make Money from Ideas, London: Penguin Global;

    Google Scholar 

  67. D. Hesmondhalgh (2002), The Cultural Industries, London: Sage Publication;

    Google Scholar 

  68. C. Herrera, (2002) ‘Cultural Capital and Its Impact on Development”, IDB Cultural Centre: Encountors, Vol. 43:1–13;

    Google Scholar 

  69. J. Heilbrun and Gray C. (2004) The Economics of Art and Culture, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  70. R. Caves (2000), Creative Industries: Contracts Between Art and Commerce, Cambridge: Harvard University Press; and J. Ko (2006) ‘Cultural Contents Industry Seeks Growth through Exports,’ SERI Economic Focus, Samsung Economic Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2014 Jitendra Uttam

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Uttam, J. (2014). Perspectives, Arguments and the Structure. In: The Political Economy of Korea. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137451248_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics