Skip to main content
  • 13 Accesses

Abstract

To have any real effect a law that seeks to alter behaviour must be used by its addressees to guide their conduct on their own initiative. If no one were influenced by a law except after the fact — when required to pay compensation for its breach — it would prove effectively impotent, for litigation — a time-consuming, costly and idiosyncratic method of enforcement — is unsuitable to ensure systematic compliance, and the sheer volume of actions would choke the enforcement machinery. The reasons why people obey laws is a large question which has received a great deal of speculation and insufficient empirical research,1 and about which it is not proposed to theorise here. Without denigrating the importance of any number of other factors, one clearly vital consideration is the threat of sanction, the deterrent effect that shapes behaviour by making compliance more attractive than the financial costs or physical and psychological punishment that follows upon noncompliance.2 Although countervailing factors pointing in the direction of immobility or active resistance may carry the day in particular instances,3* in principle a reforming statute should contain credible sanctions, readily capable of being invoked and carrying sufficient sting to stimulate its addressees to obedience. These postulates about remedies — a small sub-set of the general problem of the dynamics of legal compliance — form the criteria by which the provisions of the Act discussed in this chapter will be evaluated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 29.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. E.g. the materials collected in L. Friedman and S. Macaulay, Law and the Behavioural Sciences (Bobbs-Merrill, 2nd edn, 1977) chap. 3B

    Google Scholar 

  2. several of the essays in J. Pennock and J. Chapman (eds), Nomos XV — The Limits of Law (Lieber-Atherton, 1974); and many of the articles in Issue No. 2 of J. Soc. Iss. (1971).

    Google Scholar 

  3. On deterrence see F. Zimring and G. Hawkins, Deterrence: The Legal Threat in Crime Control (Chicago U.P., 1973), and their article in J. Soc. Iss., op. cit.; and several articles by the Norwegian scholar J. Andeneas, particularly ‘The General Preventive Effects of Punishment’, 114 U. Pa. L. Rev.949 (1966) and ‘The Morality of Deterrence’, 37 U. Chi. L. Rev. 649 (1970).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Perhaps — systematic empirical data are lacking — the most important sources of successful resistance are communal, as where a cohesive group — trade unionists, white Southerners, or nationals of a country occupied by foreigners — see the law as an imposition of the fiat of outsiders; and moral, as where users of cannabis see prohibition of its use as part of a broader attack on their way of life, or objectionable in principle. Ignorance or lack of familiarity with the legal process on the part of the protected class may also make a law ineffective even without active opposition, e.g. Aubert, ‘Some Social Functions of Legislation’, in V. Aubert (ed.) Sociology of Law (Penguin Books, 1969) chap. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  5. F. Lawson, Remedies of English Law (Penguin Books, 1972) passim.

    Google Scholar 

  6. I draw here particularly on the excellent article by Chayes, ‘The Role of the Judge in Public Law Litigation’, 89 Harv. L. Rev. 1281 (1976).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. See also D. Horowitz, The Courts and Social Policy (Brookings Institution, 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Commentators adopt the same perspective and reach the same conclusion. See A. Ogus, The Law of Damages (Butterworth, 1973) pp. 32–4

    Google Scholar 

  9. H. Street, Principles of the Law of Damages (Sweet & Maxwell, 1962) pp. 34–6.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Cf. O. Kahn-Freund, Labour and the Law (Stevens, 2nd edn, 1977) pp. 1–2, who attributes the ‘infinitestimal’ contribution of the common law to good labour relations, and its recurrent harmful forays in that area, to its individualistic orientation.

    Google Scholar 

  11. The point is well made in an otherwise rather overwrought essay by Tay, ‘Law, the Citizen and the State’, in E. Kamenka et al. (eds) Law and Society: The Crisis in Legalldeals (Edward Arnold, 1978).

    Google Scholar 

  12. See further, Handford, ‘Moral Damage in Germany’, (1978) 27 I.C.L.Q. 849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. See, e.g., the sample of cases reported in CRE, Annual Report 1978 (H.C. 128, 1979), app 11, and the remarks of Ian Macdonald, a barrister active in this area, in Runnymede Seminar, p. 13.

    Google Scholar 

  14. The leading case appears to be Patterson v. Amer. Tobacco Co., 535 F. 2d 257 (4th Circ. 1976). See, further, W. Gould, Black Workers in White Unions (Cornell U.P. 1977) pp. 147–9.

    Google Scholar 

  15. The leading case appears to be Patterson v. Amer. Tobacco Co., 535 F. 2d 257 (4th Circ. 1976). See, further, W. Gould, Black Workers in White Unions (Cornell U.P. 1977) pp. 147–9.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 1980 Laurence Lustgarten

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lustgarten, L. (1980). Individual Remedies. In: Legal Control of Racial Discrimination. Palgrave, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-16439-4_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics