Skip to main content

A Framework for Fiscal Policy Coordination and Economic Stability: Countercyclical Transfer for Infrastructure

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
State Government Budget Stabilization

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Choice ((SIPC,volume 8))

  • 924 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter examines the theory behind the design of fiscal transfers; it identifies acyclicality of transfers as a drawback and proposes countercyclical design as an optimal fiscal framework to mitigate cyclical economic fluctuations. It further advocates countercyclical transfers for infrastructure investment, service maintenance, and business tax relief as incentives for states to save in boom years then build from recession into recovery. The framework is set to operate on time-consistent policy rules, as automatic stabilizers with triggers from key economic indicators. It advocates dynamic equity to compensate boom-year donor states ­during recession for more effective macroeconomic stabilization. This chapter focuses on fiscal policy; it does not discuss the political dynamics or details in implementation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    George Soros: “The crisis was generated by the system itself.” See the Institute for New Economic Thinking, available at http://ineteconomics.org/.

  2. 2.

    For details, see “Federal Highway Trust Fund Apportionment Formulas,” available at

    http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/reports/financingfederalaid/appd.htm.

  3. 3.

    The formula of the GRS program was Statei’s share of GRS  =  Aus * [(popi * GTEFi * RIFi)/sum of 51(popi * GTEFi * RIFi)], where A  =  total appropriation, RIF  =  relative income factor  =  national average per capita income/state per cap income, and GTEF  =  general tax effort factor  =  taxes collection/total personal income.

  4. 4.

    For the estimated average length of business cycles in the twentieth century, see Hamilton 1993 and Robert Gordon 2010.

  5. 5.

    McGuire 2009 notes that the Congress held discussions about a new version of the GRS program to help state and local governments handle the budget crisis they were facing in 2009.

  6. 6.

    Seidman (2003) notes that public works projects are more likely to shift workers from their current jobs to public works jobs, thus leading to dislocation (xv). The proposed NIP with planned infrastructure work will not run into this problem.

  7. 7.

    As of the end of FY 2009, states still held BSF balances equal to 2.1% of GDP, which indicates that federal stimulus dollars had to a large extent replaced state own resources – a concern explicitly expressed by President Obama.

  8. 8.

    Taylor suggests a higher-order process as an alternative: Y t  =  a 1 Y t−1  +  a 2 Y t−2  +  u t. But this second-order autoregressive process still assumes a smooth gradual process. It is not a solution but only more “gradual.”

References

  • Albouy D (2009) The unequal geographic burden of federal taxation. J Polit Econ 117(4):635–667

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom V (1981) Studies in Swedish post-war industrial investments. Ph.D. dissertation. Uppsala University, Sweden

    Google Scholar 

  • Blinder AS (2006) The case against the case against discretionary fiscal policy. In: Kopche RW, Tootell G, Triest R (eds) The macroeconomics of fiscal policy. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradford DF, Oates WE (1971) Towards a predictive theory of intergovernmental grants. Am Econ Rev 61(2):440–448

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM (1950) Federalism and fiscal equity. Am Econ Rev 40(4):583–599

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM (1952) Federal grants and resource allocation. J Polit Econ 60(3):208–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burns A, Mitchell W (1946) Measuring the business cycle. NBER, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebold FX, Rudebusch GD (1996) Measuring business cycles: a modern perspective. Rev Econ Stat 78(1):67–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncombe WD, Hou Y (2011) Substantiation of transportation infrastructure – patterns of governance and public finance in development: an analytical comparison of the United States and China. Paper presented at the 1st China-India-US symposium on development and governance. Indian Institute of Management-Bangalore (IIMB), 21–23 Jan 2011

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1948) A monetary and fiscal framework for economic stability. Am Econ Rev 38(3):245–264

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (2010) Okun’s law and productivity innovations. Am Econ Rev 2:11–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grady A (2008) Medicaid: the federal medical assistance percentage. Congressional Research Service, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J (1989) A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57(2):357–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J (1993) Estimation, inference, and forecasting of time series subject to changes in regime. In: Maddala GS, Rao CR, Vinod HD (eds) Handbook of statistics, vol 11. North-Holland, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins HP (1951) Fiscal equity in the unequal treatment of unequals: a suggested test. J Polit Econ 59:353–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim CJ, Nelson CR (1999) State-space models with regime switching. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85(3):473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A (1974) Swedish economic policy. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Maguire S (2009) General revenue sharing: background and analysis. Congressional Research Service, RL 31936, 9 Jan 2009. Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Office of Legislative and Governmental Affairs, United States Department of Transportation (2007) Financing federal-aid highways. FHWA-PL-07-017

    Google Scholar 

  • Rich MJ (1989) Distributive politics and the allocation of federal grants. Am Polit Sci Rev 83(1):193–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott AD (1950) A note on grants in federal countries. Economica 17:416–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seidman LS (2003) Automatic fiscal policies to combat recessions. M.E. Sharp, Armonk

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (2002) Is fiscal policy possible? Is it desirable? Presidential address to the XIII World Congress of the International Economic Association, Lisbon

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein H (1996) The fiscal revolution in America: policy in pursuit of reality. The AEI Press, Washington, DC, 2nd revised edition

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1982) The Swedish investment funds system as a stabilization policy rule. Brook Papers Econ Act 1:57–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice, vol 39, Carnegie-Rochester series on public policy. North-Holland, New York, pp 195–214

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Census Bureau. Annual survey of state and local government finances and census of governments, since 1951

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang W, Hou Y (2009) Pay-go financing and stability of capital spending. Public Budg Finance 29(4):90–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast BR, Shepsle KA, Johnsen C (1981) The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. J Polit Econ 89(4):642–664

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: A Model of Countercyclical Infrastructure Investment

Appendix: A Model of Countercyclical Infrastructure Investment

1.1 Taylor’s Model for Multi-period Construction Projects

John Taylor (1982) devised a model for multiple-period construction projects (hereafter “Taylor’s model”) that well suits my topic. Here I use the Taylor’s model to illustrate why and how a countercyclical stabilization program of infrastructure investment may work in theory.

As discussed in Section 4.1, better infrastructure leads to higher productivity. We can take total existing infrastructure as capital and the building of new infrastructure as accumulating capital stock. Infrastructure takes time to build, with construction duration varying from 1 to 3 years (census data on construction projects show that this is a reasonable assumption). Thus, we can establish a capital accumulation equation:

$$ {K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}={K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}-1}+{S}_{\rm{t}}-h{K}_{t+n-1}, $$
(11.1)

where Kt is capital stock at the beginning of year t, S t is the level of construction project starts in year t, and h is the rate of deterioration (or depreciation) of existing infrastructure.

Depreciation reduces the value, or capital stock, of infrastructure; deterioration requires either advance resource reserves for replacement or current year outlay for maintenance of existing structure and facilities. Infrastructure is expensive to build, so governments try to minimize the expected cost of building them; thus, we have a cost equation:

$$ {\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{t}=1}^{\infty }{b}^{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}}\left[\rm{d}/2{(v{Y}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}-{K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}})}^{2}+{c}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}{I}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}\right],$$
(11.2)

where b is a discount factor, Y t is exogenous demand for infrastructure, I t is infrastructure investment in year t, v is the desired or optimal infrastructure-GDP ratio, and c t is cost of investment goods in year t.

Demands for infrastructure (Y t), capital stock (K t), investment (I t), project starts (S t), and cost (c t) are all cyclical deviations from their secular growth trend; so their long-run averages are zeroes. If a project is completed within 1 year and thus its value is accounted for in the stock in the same year, then I t  =  S t. Demand for infrastructure is exogenously driven and determined by demographic and other factors that are external to the government. The infrastructure-GDP ratio (v) is assumed to be constant since we consider the cyclical (short-term) changes in the relative cost (c t) of investment into infrastructure. The quadratic term in the cost function implies a U-shaped cost of having too little or too much infrastructure relative to the demand.

In order to minimize the cost, a level of project starts is chosen, as indicated by the project starts equation:

$$ {S}_{\rm{t}}=v{Y}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}-(1-h){K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}-1}-({b}^{-\rm{n}}/\rm{d}){\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{i}=0}^{\rm{n}-1}{b}^{\rm{i}}{\rm{w}}_{\rm{i}+1}\left({\rm{C}}_{\rm{t}+1}-b(1-h){\rm{C}}_{\rm{t}+\rm{i}-1}\right)}\rm,$$
(11.3)

where K t + n −1 is predetermined at time t and wi is the fraction of expenditure on projects during the ith year of construction.

It is reasonable to assume I  =  1, 2, 3 because most projects are normally completed within 3 years. Project starts in year t are determined by the estimated demand n years later; estimates are done in the infrastructure improvement (capital ­budgeting) process and are given in the capital budget. This estimated number of project starts is also the discounted and expenditure-weighted sum of investment costs in the next n years. In other words, this equation discounts the expected gap in infrastructure n years into the future (which can be seen by multiplying the right-hand side by b n); the optimal level of starts is a weighted average of the infrastructure gap and the infrastructure outlay to close the gap.

In the process of federal infrastructure improvement planning or state capital budgeting, forecasts are (have to be) made on infrastructure demand nationwide or in each state. These are done with data from the past years; we can assume that it is done with an autoregressive model. The forecasting equation is

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{\widehat{Y}}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}}={\alpha }^{\rm{n}}{Y}_{\rm{t}}, 0\le \rm\rm\alpha \rm\rm\le \rm\rm1\end{array}$$
(11.4)

Autoregressive forecasts are the best that federal and state governments can do about the unknown future, but such forecasts are not in line with shocks to demand from business cycle fluctuations. (Section 3.2, below, will dwell on this.) To better handle the drastic cyclical shocks, an infrastructure investment stabilization policy can be designed, with the following policy rule equation to calculate the expected future cost of infrastructure outlay:

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{\widehat{\rm{C}}}_{\rm{t}+\rm{i}}=\rm{g}{\alpha }^{\rm{i}}{\rm{Y}}_{\rm{t}}, i=1,2,\mathrm{....}\end{array}$$
(11.5)

where g is a positive policy parameter. As infrastructure demand fluctuates around the long-run trend, the effective price of investment goods moves in the same direction. Substituting Eqs. 11.4 and 11.5 into 11.3, the project starts equation, we obtain

$$ {S}_{\rm{t}}={A}_{\rm{n}}{Z}_{\rm{t}}+h{K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}-1},$$
(11.6)

where \( {A}_{\rm{n}}=\upsilon {\alpha }^{\rm{n}}-({b}^{-\rm{n}}/\rm{d})g{\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{i}=0}^{\rm{n}-1}{\alpha }^{\rm{i}}{b}^{\rm{i}}{\rm{w}}_{\rm{i}+1}\left(1-\alpha b(1-h)\right)}\)and \( {z}_{\rm{t}}={Y}_{\rm{t}}-{Y}_{\rm{t}-1}\).

The first term (A n z t) is net investment, and the second is replacement of the portion of capital stock that depreciates between years. Net investment materializes through a linear accelerator mechanism. A is the accelerator coefficient; it is positively related to the desired infrastructure ratio, v, and negatively related to the depreciation rate, h. The faster the depreciation, the more expensive it is to maintain a given size of infrastructure stock.

The accelerator (A) and its response to the stabilization policy (g) both depend on n. Thus, the stabilization policy has different total and marginal effects for each value of the length of construction. Infrastructure in year t is now a distributed lag of starts over n years, with lag weight being weights for new value:

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{I}_{\rm{t}}={\rm{w}}_{1}{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}+{\rm{w}}_{2}{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-1}+\dots +{\rm{w}}_{\rm{n}}{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-\rm{n}+1}, {\rm{w}}_{1}+{\rm{w}}_{2}+\cdots +{\rm{w}}_{\rm{n}}=1,\end{array}$$
(11.7)

Therefore, the n-year infrastructure outlay equation is a distributed lag ­accelerator equation:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{I}_{\rm{t}}={A}_{\rm{n}}({w}_{1}{z}_{\rm{t}}+{w}_{2}{z}_{\rm{t}-1}+\dots +{w}_{\rm{n}}{z}_{\rm{t}-\rm{n}+1})+h({w}_{1}{K}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}-1}+\dots +{w}_{\rm{n}}{K}_{\rm{t}})\\ \rm{ }\rm\rm={\rm{A}}_{\rm{n}}{\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{i}=0}^{\rm{n}-1}{\rm{w}}_{\rm{i}+1}{\rm{z}}_{\rm{t}-1}{\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{i}=1}^{\rm{n}}{\rm{w}}_{\rm{i}}{\rm{K}}_{\rm{t}+\rm{n}-\rm{i}}}}\end{array}$$
(11.8)

1.2 Two-State Regime Switching

Over 60 years ago the famous study by Burns and Mitchell (1946) told us that the evolution of the business cycle is nonlinear, with regime switching at turning points of the cycle. The Taylor model was devised in the early 1980s. Though the author saw the need for a two-state switching component, it was computationally “very complicated.” By the late 1980s advances in time series techniques provided the tools for the breakthrough. In this section I bring in a two-state regime switching component, developed by James Hamilton, to extend the Taylor model.

Incremental forecasts are the best that federal and state governments can do, but they are not in line with shocks to demand from business cycle fluctuations. In the autoregressive forecasting Eq., 11.4, infrastructure demand deviates around (above or below) the secular trend; the deviations are expected to return to the trend gradually over time. That is, assuming demand deviations are due from a simple first-order autoregressive process: Y t  =  a i Y t - 1  -  u t, which is a gradual, continuous process, typical of normal years in a boom but not characteristic of the business cycle.

From the perspective of business cycles, infrastructure demands embed “turning points” that are transition from the expansionary phase (peak) into the contraction phase, and then from contraction (trough) back into expansion (Burns and Mitchell 1946). These turning points are regime switching from boom to bust and back to boom.Footnote 8 Hamilton (1993) and Kim and Nelson (1999) provide the algorithm for such a model.

In his seminal paper, Hamilton (1989) proposed a tractable approach to modeling regime changes. He uses the parameters in an autoregression as the outcome of a discrete-state Markov process, which draws probabilistic inferences on the unobservable regime changes with a nonlinear iterative filter that he devised an algorithm for. Research prior to this paper assumed linear stationary process in the first difference of the log of key macroindicator series; Hamilton proposed that these series follow a nonlinear stationary process (Hamilton 1989, 357). The ­macroeconomy switches between a fast growth phase and a slow (even negative) growth phase of the cycle; the switch is governed by a Markov process (ibid, 362). The Kalman filter is a linear algorithm for continuous unobserved state vectors; the Markov filter that Hamilton devises provides nonlinear inferences which can well handle the phase switches of business cycles.

The Hamilton’s Markov model of trend is (different from Section 3.1, s here indicates state)

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{\rm{n}}_{\rm{t}}=\rm\rm{\alpha }_{1}{\rm{s}}_{\rm{t}}+\rm\rm{\alpha }_{0}+{\rm{n}}_{\rm{t}-1}, {\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=0\rm{or}1,\end{array}$$
(11.9)

The transition between states is governed by a stochastic first-order Markov process that is strictly stationary, with the following probability functions:

$$ Pr[{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=1|{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-1}=1]=p,$$
$$ Pr[{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=0|{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-1}=1]=1-p,$$
(11.10)
$$ Pr[{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=0|{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-1}=0]=q,$$
$$ Pr[{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=1|{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}-1}=0]=1-p.$$

The stochastic stationary process follows an AR(1) representation:

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t}}=(1-\rm{q})+l{\rm{S}}_{\rm{t-}1}+{\rm{v}}_{\rm{t}}, l\equiv -1+\rm{p}+\rm{q,}\end{array} $$
(11.11)

where conditional on S t - 1  =  1, V t  =  (1  −  p), with probability p and V t  =  −  p, with probability 1  −  p; where conditional on S t  −  1  =  0, V t  =  −  (1  −  q), with probability q, V t  =  q, with probability 1  −  q. Equation 11.9 is a special case of a standard ARIMA model with normally distributed error terms (taken as “innovations”); V t in Eq. 11.11 is uncorrelated with lagged values of S t, such that

$$ \begin{array}{cc}E\left[{V}_{t}|{S}_{t-j}=1\right]=E\left[{V}_{t}|{S}_{t-j}=0\right]=0,\rm \rm{for}j=1,\rm2,\rm\dots \end{array}$$
(11.12)

Hamilton highlights two differences between Eq. 11.9 and a standard ARIMA. Under the Hamilton’s Markov model of trend, the first difference growth rate (n tn t−1) changes as response to regime switches, but does not necessarily do so in every period. When this model is applied to a linear normal process, it generates a nonlinear process (Hamilton 1989, 362).

1.3 Model Integration

To link the two-state Markov regime switching with the identification of actual business cycles, Diebold and Rudebusch (1996) cleverly rewrite Eq. 11.10 as a transition probability matrix:

$$ \rm{M}=\left[\begin{array}{cc}{\rm{p}}_{00} 1-{\rm{p}}_{000}\\ 1-{\rm{p}}_{11} {\rm{p}}_{11}\end{array}\right],$$
(11.13)

and treat regime switching as different probabilistic objects. We can take \( {\left\{{\rm{y}}_{\rm{t}}\right\}}_{\rm{t}=1}^{\rm{T}}\)as the path of the observed time series. In our case, it is the macroeconomic indicator, GDP, or infrastructure investment. \( {\left\{{\rm{y}}_{\rm{t}}\right\}}_{\rm{t}=1}^{\rm{T}}\)depends on the state, \( {\left\{{S}_{\rm{t}}\right\}}_{\rm{t}=1}^{\rm{T}}\). Thus, the density of y t is conditional on s t, as in

$$ f({\rm{y}}_{\rm{t}}{|}_{S}{}_{\rm{t}};\theta )=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi \sigma }}\mathrm{exp}\left[\frac{-{({\rm{y}}_{\rm{t}}-\rm\rm\mu {\rm{s}}_{\rm{t}})}^{2}}{2{\sigma }^{2}}\right].$$
(11.14)

Based on this, they proposed a multivariate dynamic factor model with Markov regime switching:

$$ P({f}_{\rm{t}}|{h}_{\rm{t}};\theta )=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi \rm{ }\sigma }}\mathrm{exp}\left[\frac{-{\left[({f}_{\rm{t}}-\rm\rm{\mu }_{{\rm{s}}_{\rm{t}}})-{\displaystyle {\sum }_{\rm{i}=1}^{\rm{p}}{\varphi }_{\rm{i}}({f}_{\rm{t-i}}-{\mu }_{{s}_{\rm{t-i}}})}\right]}^{2}}{2\rm{}{\sigma }^{2}}\right],$$
(11.15)

where \( {\left\{{f}_{\rm{t}}\right\}}_{\rm{t}=1}^{\rm{T}}\)is the sample path of our key factor (infrastructure or GDP). The conditional density summarizes the probabilistic dependence of f t on h t. The key factor moves around two means: μ 0 is recession and μ1 is boom. In a regression representation, it is

$$ \Delta {x}_{\rm{t}}=b+l{f}_{\rm{t}}+{\mu }_{\rm{t}},D(L){\mu }_{\rm{t}}={\epsilon }_{\rm{t}}. $$
(11.16)

The dimension of all elements is (N  ×  1) except \( D(L)\)which is (N  ×  N) and f which is (1  ×  1). Thus, econometricians have shown that a time-consistent stabilization policy can work in theory on infrastructure investment. My next step is to integrate infrastructure into a federal program and into state capital budgets; see Section 4.4 of the paper “Putting Infrastructure into Federal/State Programs.”

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hou, Y. (2013). A Framework for Fiscal Policy Coordination and Economic Stability: Countercyclical Transfer for Infrastructure. In: State Government Budget Stabilization. Studies in Public Choice, vol 8. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-6061-9_11

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-6061-9_11

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New York, NY

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-6060-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-6061-9

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics