Skip to main content

Option pricing in continuous time

  • Chapter
Financial Securities

Part of the book series: The Current Issues in Finance Series ((CIF))

  • 76 Accesses

Abstract

The method of pricing financial securities in discrete time, studied in the previous chapter, makes use of an arbitrary concept: that of the unitary holding period of financial securities. In fact, we considered two successive instants t and t + 1, put into place an arbitrage portfolio at instant t, then examined the rebalancing of this operation at instant t + 1, the interval of time between t and t + 1 being fixed and given. A procedure of this type excludes the possibility of rebalancing at an intermediate instant. In practice, however, investors are free to operate on the financial market at any time.1 A more natural procedure therefore involves using a continuous timescale. It is in this spirit that we showed in the previous chapter what the price limit of an option would be if we indefinitely reduced the interval of time between two successive instants. This procedure is, however, indirect. We shall now study, and apply to option pricing, a mathematical technique allowing us to reason directly in continuous time: the technique of stochastic differential calculus.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes to Chapter 7

  1. Of course they are sometimes prevented from doing so by transactions costs and by difficulty in finding a counterpart. But arbitrarily fixing the interval of time between two successive transactions will obviously not take account of these two phenomena.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Intuitively, we denote by random ‘process’ a random variable whose probability distribution changes over time. In more rigorous terms, this is a family of random variables indexed by a parameter. This parameter, in all the applications we consider, will be time. It belongs to the set of non-negative real numbers. The set of processes indexed by a real number is constructed from the set of processes indexed by an integer in the same manner as we construct the set of real numbers from the set of integers. We arrive at a fundamental theorem whose existence is due to Kolmogorov.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Discontinuous price processes are dealt with by [Cox and Ross 1976].

    Google Scholar 

  4. In precise terms, a process is said to be continuous when the probability that a trajectory of this process is a continuous function of time is equal to 1.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Cf. [Feller 1966], page 210, or [Métivier 1979] page 214.

    Google Scholar 

  6. [Bachelier 1900], [Einstein 1905, 1906].

    Google Scholar 

  7. See [Karatzas and Shreve 1988], page 82.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Reminder: a sum of multivariate normal random variables is a normal random variable.

    Google Scholar 

  9. And when the time difference between instants t and t + 1 is equal to one unit of time.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Here, we assume a division into equal intervals to keep the explanation simple. In fact, this is not necessary. The more general condition commonly imposed on a partition t i. i = l...n of the interval of time [t, t + τ](t n = t + τ) is that: Maxi. |t i − t i −1 → 0 when n → ∞.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See [Duffie 1988], p. 248 et seq., [Karatzas and Shreve 1988], p. 66 et seq. According to Donsker’s theorem, there is convergence towards a Brownian even if the probability distribution of the increases z t + 1−z t is not normal. By virtue of the Central Limit theorem, it is sufficient that the increases are independent and of the same variance.

    Google Scholar 

  12. From now on, the symbol σ2 indicates the variance per unit of time.

    Google Scholar 

  13. It is customary, in fact, to keep stochastic differential equations such as [1.7] in a form containing the differential elements dt and dz. It is not good practice to produce ‘derivatives’ by dividing both sides of Equation 1.7 by dt. The reason for this precaution is (see Appendix 1) that the trajectories of a Brownian are extremely erratic (non-smooth) and non-differentiable.

    Google Scholar 

  14. See Appendix 2 for the definition of the stochastic integral; in particular condition A2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Cf [Arnold 1974], pages 105 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  16. There is, however, a significant difference between these two classes of process. Diffusion processes are, by definition, Markovian processes, whose movement depends only on the current value of the variable, whilst the class of Itö processes may be widened: a( ) and σ( ) may depend on past values of x.

    Google Scholar 

  17. But, purely on account of the fact that the drift depends on x, the variance of an increase in x over a finite interval of time will also depend on x.

    Google Scholar 

  18. And by using the expression of (dx) 2 which results from this: (dx) 2 = σ2 (x,t)dt.

    Google Scholar 

  19. An Itö’s Lemma also exists for functions of several random processes y =f(x 1, x 2, t). It brings in the covariance between the random parts of x 1 and x 2.

    Google Scholar 

  20. It is positive in Figure 7.4.

    Google Scholar 

  21. We should also ensure that the functions α and σ are such that stochastic differential equation 2.1 possesses one and only one solution, that is to say that they satisfy the growth condition and the Lipschitz condition.

    Google Scholar 

  22. When reproducing a call option b is negative. In fact, this is then a borrowing position on the risk-free security.

    Google Scholar 

  23. The true mathematical meaning of Equation 2.6 is that of the corresponding integral equation giving the increase in value of the portfolio over an interval of time [0, τ]: \( V_\tau - V_0 = \int_0^\tau {h_t dS_t } + \int_0^\tau {b_t D_t rDt = \int_0^\tau {\left[ {h_t S_t \alpha _t + b_t D_t r} \right]dt + } } \int_0^\tau {h_t S_t \sigma _t dz_t } \)It is the first term on the right-hand side of the first line of this equation, or the last term of the second line, which requires the stochastic integral with respect to a Brownian to be defined (see Appendix 2). For this integral to exist, the integrability condition [A2.4] must be imposed on the portfolio: As we show in Appendix 2, it is this condition which prevents the portions invested in the risky security from growing indefinitely and which forbids strategies of the ‘doubling strategy’ type (see the introduction to Part II). From an economic point of view, this is a condition of solvency.

    Google Scholar 

  24. This is a notable advantage of this argument over Black and Scholes’ original argument [Black and Scholes 1973]. Moreover, the present argument, as opposed to that of Black and Scholes, does not assume a priori that the price of the option is a twice differentiable function of the price of the underlying security. Here we constructed, without referring to the option, a twice differentiable function V. We then showed that the price of the option had to be identical to that of this function V.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See [Karatzas and Shreve 1988], page 267.

    Google Scholar 

  26. The change from drift α to drift r of the underlying asset induces a change in the probability distribution of the future values of S. If we know the ‘true’ probability distribution of these future values in the presence of drift a, we may obtain the ‘adjusted’ distribution resulting from a drift equal to r by means of the Girsanov theorem: see [Karatzas and Shreve 1988], page 190 or [Lipster and Shiryayev 1977], page 232.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Holding and storage costs may occur in relation to options on commodity or currency.

    Google Scholar 

  28. If we were in the presence of a tax system hitting dividends and capital gains differently, we could be less definite and assume that the drop in price is proportional to the dividend: we would then have to specify a coefficient of proportionality.

    Google Scholar 

  29. The opposite specification, in which the amount of dividend D actually paid on the date T is limited by the total assets available, can only be solved by numerical methods (Section 7.4).

    Google Scholar 

  30. See Geske’s article [Geske 1979a], or [Cox and Rubinstein 1985], page 414.

    Google Scholar 

  31. The ‘ordinary’ Geske formula, giving the price of an option on an option, calls in the bivariate normal distribution function, which must be calculated by numerical integration. The valuation of complex compound options ‘on several levels’ (an option on an option on an option...) requires numeric calculation of the multivariate normal law, which is extremely laborious.

    Google Scholar 

  32. An option gives the right to receive one security in exchange for another. Most often, one of the two securities is cash: a call is the right to receive a security in exchange for cash; a put is the right to receive cash in exchange for a security. We are speaking here of the dividend attached to the security that is received.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Recall that some options obey partial differential equation 3.3 rather than Equation 2.3.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Clearly, it is not the cash received itself which brings about the exercise before maturity. Without the plan to reinvest this cash, there would be no hurry to receive it.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Remember that the path of S is continuous. We assume here that: S(0) >S*(0), otherwise the option is exercised at instant 0.

    Google Scholar 

  36. The effective value of the put is then given by the curve to the right of point B and, to the left of this point, by the segment giving the exercise price S − K. This generally results in a kink in B.

    Google Scholar 

  37. We are reproducing here the reasoning of [Merton 1973], note 60.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See [Dumas 1991].

    Google Scholar 

  39. Note, however, that we obtained condition 4.4 from the condition: ∂P/∂S* = 0, which is of the marginal type. We assume here a small movement of the exercise frontier.

    Google Scholar 

  40. In the conclusion to this chapter, we review again the cases in which explicit, exact or approximate solutions are feasible and desirable.

    Google Scholar 

  41. That is, we count the time backwards, j = 0 corresponding to the date of (terminal) maturity of the option.

    Google Scholar 

  42. The reader will find a complete treatment of this method in [Smith 1978].

    Google Scholar 

  43. This is known as a tridiagonal structure.

    Google Scholar 

  44. It should be added that the finite difference method is applicable to American options. Exercise before maturity is taken into account by an additional stage of calculation: after calculating the prices of the non-exercised option on line j + 1, as shown, we need only compare them with the exercised price and keep the larger of the two before moving to the next time stage.

    Google Scholar 

  45. This method is known as an ‘implicit method’ as it calculates derivatives from values which are still unknown, which must be obtained by solving a system of simultaneous equations. The ‘explicit’ method would evaluate these derivatives at instant j, at which time all the values are already known. After substituting into the differential equation, the unknown value of C at point i at instant j + 1 would appear only once in the ith equation, in the term C t. We could then solve each equation separately. This would be simpler, but the method is unfortunately often unstable (numerical errors will be magnified when moving from one line to the next). Furthermore, this method would introduce a similar bias, but with the opposite sign to that which we are about to describe in respect of the implicit method. We shall see that this bias may be eliminated by using an average of the implicit evaluation and the explicit evaluation of the derivatives with respect to S.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Expressions 5.1 represent, it will be recalled, (see previous note) the implicit method.

    Google Scholar 

  47. The derivatives estimated at instant j would be obtained by expressions analogous to [5.1] where j + 1 had been replaced by j.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See also [Smith 1978].

    Google Scholar 

  49. Here we give what is known as the Euler approximation. We may also simulate, with greater precision, the process solution to a stochastic differential equation using Runge-Kutta stochastic approximation. See [Rumelin 1982].

    Google Scholar 

  50. Most spreadsheets and statistical software are programmed with a function to generate numbers at random.

    Google Scholar 

  51. On the Monte Carlo technique applied to options, see, for example, [Boyle 1987].

    Google Scholar 

  52. The same method may be applied to the binomial technique of Chapter 6. The binomial technique is implemented twice: once for the main problem which we wish to solve and once for the control problem. Comparing the binomial solution of the control problem with its exact solution then provides an indication as to the error made in the binomial solution of the main problem and allows this to be rectified. See [Hull and White 1988].

    Google Scholar 

  53. We leave aside the formulae which apply to cases where the underlying asset may undergo jumps (mentioned in Chapter 6) or formulae linked to American options, the only known formulae being those which apply to American options with infinite maturity.

    Google Scholar 

  54. The ‘variation’ of a path is the length of the line which draws it.

    Google Scholar 

  55. We assume here a partition into equal intervals for ease of explanation. In fact, this is not necessary. See note 10 above.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Using slightly stronger hypotheses, it may even be shown that this equation is true almost certainly (that is with a probability equal to 1). See [Lipster and Shiryayev 1988], page 89.

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Equation A2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  58. This may be found, for example, in [Karatzas and Shreve 1988], page 137 or [Lipster and Shiryayev 1988], page 103.

    Google Scholar 

  59. See the much more precise definition of ‘adapted’ processes in the books already cited.

    Google Scholar 

  60. See [Dybvig and Huang 1988].

    Google Scholar 

References

  1. L. Arnold, Stochastic Differential Equations: Theory and Applications. John Wiley & Sons, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  2. L. Bachelier, 1900, Théorie de la spéculation, Annales des Sciences de l’Ecole Normale Supérieure, 3, 21-86, reproduced in P. H. Gootner, ed., The Random Character of Stock Market Prices. MIT Press, Cambridge, 1964.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Analytic Approximation of American Option Values, The Journal of Finance, 42, 1987, 301-320.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Y. Z. Bergman, A Characterization of Self-financing Portfolio Strategies, Working Paper, Institute of Business and Economic Research, University of California, Berkeley, 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  5. F. Black and M. Scholes, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 1973, 637–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. M. J. Brennan, The Pricing of Contingent Claims in Discrete-Time Models, Journal of Finance, 34, 1979, 53–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. P. Carr, Option Pricing When Dividends and Interest Rates are Unknown, Working Paper, University of California, Los Angeles, August 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  8. G. Courtadon, A More Accurate Finite Difference Approximation for the Valuation of Options, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, XVIII, 1982, 697–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. J. C. Cox and S. A. Ross, The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 1976, 145–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. J. C. Cox and M. Rubinstein, Options Markets. Prentice Hall, Inc., 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  11. [Cox et al. 1979]_J. G. Cox, S. Ross and M. Rubinstein, Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach, Journal of Financial Economies, 7, 1979, 229–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. P. Crank and P. Nicholson, A Practical Method for Numerical Evaluation of Solutions of Partial Differential Equations of the Heat-conduction type, Proc. Camb Phil. Soc, 43, 1947, 50–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. G. Dahlquist and Å. Björck, Numerical Methods, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  14. D. Duffle, Security Markets, Stochastic Models. Academic Press, Inc., 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  15. B. Dumas, Super Contact and Related Optimality Conditions, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 15, 1991, 675–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. P. H. Dybvig and C.-R Huang, Nonnegative Wealth, Absence of Arbitrage, and Feasible Consumption Plans, Review of Financial Studies, 1, 1988, 377–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. A. Einstein, Annalen der Physik, 17, 1905, 549ff., reproduced as On the Movement of Small Particles Suspended in a Stationary Liquid Demanded by the Molecular Kinetic Theory of Heat, in A. Einstein, Investigations on the Theory of the Brownian Movement. R. Fürth, ed., Dover Publications, 1956.

    Google Scholar 

  18. A. Einstein, Zur Theorie der Brownschen Bewegung, Annalen der Physik, 19, 1906, 371–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. S. J. Farlow, Partial Differential Equations for Scientists and Engineers. John Wiley & Sons, 1982.

    Google Scholar 

  20. W. Feller, An Introduction to Probability Theory and its Applications, Volume II. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1966.

    Google Scholar 

  21. R. Geske, The Valuation of Compound Options, Journal of Financial Economics, 1979, 7, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. R. Geske, A Note on an Analytical Valuation Formula for Unprotected American Gall Options on Stocks with Known Dividends, Journal of Financial Economics, 1979, 7, 375–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. R. Geske and H. E. Johnson, The American Put Valued Analytically, Journal of Finance, 39,1984,1511–1524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. O. Grabbe, The Pricing of Gall and Put Options on Foreign Exchange, Journal of International Money and Finance, 2, 1983, 239–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. M. Harrison and D. Kreps, Martingales and Multiperiod Securities Markets, Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 1979, 381–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. P. Levy, Processus stochastiques et mouvement brownien, 2nd edition. Gauthier-Villars, Paris, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  27. J. Hull and A. White, The Use of the Control Variate Technique in Option Pricing, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 23, 1988, 237–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. J. E. Ingersoll Jr., Theory of Financial Decision Making. Rowman & Littlefield, 1987.

    Google Scholar 

  29. K. Itö, Stochastic Integral, Proc. Imperial Acad. Tokyo, 20, 1944, 519–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. K. Itö, On a Stochastic Integral Equation, Proceedings of the Japanese Academy, 1, 1946, 32–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. K. Itö, On Stochastic Differential Equations, Memoir of the American Mathematical Society, 4, 1951, 51.

    Google Scholar 

  32. I. Karatzas and S. E. Shreve, Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. Springer Verlag, 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  33. R. S. Lipster and A. N. Shiryayev, Statistics of Random Processes I: General Theory. Springer Verlag, 1977.

    Google Scholar 

  34. L. W. MacMillan, Analytical Approximation for the American Put Option, Advances in Futures and Options Research, 1, 1986, 119–139.

    Google Scholar 

  35. R. G. Merton, Theory of Rational Option Pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4, Spring 1973, 141–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. R. G. Merton, On the Pricing of Contingent Claims and the Modigliani-Miller Theorem, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 1977, 241–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. M. Métivier, Notions fondamentales de la théorie des probabilités. Dunod, 1979.

    Google Scholar 

  38. H. Reinhard, Equations aux dérivées partielles. Dunod, 1987.

    Google Scholar 

  39. R. Roll, An Analytical Valuation Formula for Unprotected American Call Options on Stocks with Known Dividends, Journal of Financial Economies, 5, 1977, 251–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. M. Rubinstein, The Valuation of Uncertain Income Stress and the Pricing of Options, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 7, 1976, 551–571.

    Google Scholar 

  41. W. Rumelin, Numerical Treatment of Stochastic Differential Equations, Siam Journal, 19, 1982, 604–613.

    Google Scholar 

  42. G. D. Smith, Numerical Solution of Partial Differential Equations: Finite Difference Methods. Oxford University Press, 1978.

    Google Scholar 

  43. N. Wiener, Differential Space, Journal of Mathematical Physics, 2, 1923, 131–174.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1996 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dumas, B., Allaz, B. (1996). Option pricing in continuous time. In: Financial Securities. The Current Issues in Finance Series. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-7116-6_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-7116-6_7

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-538-84777-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4899-7116-6

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics