Skip to main content

A Political Philosophy of Public Goods

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
European Republicanism
  • 289 Accesses

Abstract

In order to make public good theory applicable to the republican discourse, it needs to be revised. This chapter illustrates especially the dichotomy and definition problem of public good theory. The dichotomy problem is solved by combining public good theory with political philosophy. The classical public good characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry are now derived, building on Searleā€™s social constructivism, from the characteristics of a mental and a material word. Building on this new viewpoint of public good theory, the concept of a hierarchy of nested social institutions and public goods is developed that needs to be delivered by a sovereign. This approach allows to combine economic and political science theory and to explain European integration under the republican viewpoint of a res publica of public goods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Samuelson advanced a Keynesian view on economics.

  2. 2.

    In a judgement taken already in the 1980s, the German constitutional court argued that in a situation in which a citizen does not know anymore who holds which information about him, the single person will probably adopt his behaviour to this uncertainty. This adoption of behaviour undermines basic democratic processes of decision-making (see VolkszƤhlungsurteil, BVerfG, Urteil v. 15. Dezember 1983, Az. 1 BvR 209, 269, 362, 420, 440, 484/83).

  3. 3.

    Furthermore, the refugee crisis has shown that it is a club with rather high costs of exclusion.

  4. 4.

    Literally it says ā€œA well regulated Militia, being necessary to the security of a free State, the right of the people to keep and bear Arms, shall not be infringedā€. It has historical origins in the English Bill of Rights of 1689, when (protestants) tried to limit the authority of the King and contain Catholic influence.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1970), Political and economic evaluation of social effects and externalities. In The analysis of public output. Ann Arbor: UMI.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(3), 351ā€“379

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Baumol, W. J., & Oates, W. (1988). The theory of environmental policy (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    BookĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1ā€“14.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Collignon, S. (2017). The European Union as a republic. In The governance of European public goods. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Chapter 3.

    ChapterĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521477185.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Eisenhower, D. D. (1961, January 17). Farewell radio and television address to the American people.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science New Series, 162(3859), 1243ā€“1248.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hobbes, T. (2008/1651). Leviathan. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Marshall, A. (1920/1890). Principles of economics (8th ed.). London: MacMillan.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Meade, J. E. (1952). External economies and diseconomies in a competitive situation. The Economic Journal, 62(245), 54ā€“67.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Meade, J. E. (1973). The theory of economic externalities: The control of environmental pollution and similar social costs. Geneva: Institut Universitaire de Hautes Etudes Internationales. ISBN 9028604332.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Musgrave, R. (1959). The theory of public finance: A study in public economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Musgrave, R. (1969). Provision for social goods. In J. Margolis & H. Guitton (Eds.), Public economics (pp. 124ā€“144). London: Macmillan.

    ChapterĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Olson, M. (2009/1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674041660.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521405997.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Ostrom, E., Burger, J., & Field, C. B. (1999). Revisting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science, New Series, 284(5412), 278ā€“282.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Pickardt, M. (2006). Fifty years after Samuelsonā€™s the pure theory of public expenditure. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(4), 439ā€“460.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Pigou, A. C. (2013). The economics of welfare. Hountmills, Basingstone: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9781137375629.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Plato. (1980/ca. 380 BC). The Republic. In The collected dialogues (pp. 575ā€“844). Princeton: Hamilton, Edith and Huntington, Cairns, Princeton University Press.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387ā€“389.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 37(4), 350ā€“356.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1969). Pure theory of public expenditure and taxation. In J. Margolis & H. Guitton (Eds.), Public economics (pp. 8ā€“123). London: Macmillan.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Schwanitz, D. (2002). BildungĀ ā€“ Alles, was man wissen muss. Vollstaendige Taschenbuchausgabe (7 Auflage, edition). MĆ¼nchen: Goldmann Verlag. ISBN 978-3-442-15147-9.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Searle, J. R. (1996). The construction of social reality. London: Penguin Books Ltd.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Smith, A. (2003/1776). The wealth of nations (An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations). New York: Bantam Dell.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Tilly, C. (1993). Coercion, capital and European States AD 990 - 1992. Oxford: Wiley. ISBN 978-1-55786-368-3.

    Google ScholarĀ 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thilo Zimmermann .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

Ā© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Zimmermann, T. (2019). A Political Philosophy of Public Goods. In: European Republicanism . Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-25935-8_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-25935-8_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-25934-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-25935-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics