Skip to main content

Asymmetric Exchange Rate Pass-Through: Evidence, Inflation Dynamics and Policy Implications for Brazil (1999–2016)

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Brazilian Economy since the Great Financial Crisis of 2007/2008

Abstract

We investigate the existence of an asymmetry in the exchange rate pass-through to the Brazilian consumer price index (CPI). Using a decomposition of the exchange rate series, into appreciations and depreciations of the Brazilian currency during the 1999–2016 period, we estimate Structural Vector Auto-regression (SVAR) models with different identifying restrictions. The results are robust and indicate a relevant asymmetric behavior of the exchange rate pass-through. Estimates indicate a pass-through of 16% in case of depreciation and of 5.8% in case of appreciation of Brazilian Real (BRL) against the US Dollar. Accordingly, the inflationary effect resulted from a (systematic) depreciation is only partially compensated by a deflationary effect of an (systematic) appreciation of the same magnitude, generating an inflationary bias that may cast doubts on inflation control strategies based solely on inflation targeting. Results provide a case against excess exchange volatility and capital mobility. A stable exchange rate favors price stability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Portuguese, Banco Central do Brasil.

  2. 2.

    Calculated by the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE) and considered the official inflation index of the country.

  3. 3.

    In Brazil, the basic interest rate goes by the acronym (Selic) for Sistema Especial de Liquidação e de Custódia (Special System for Settlement and Custody ), which is the settlement system for most domestic securities of the Brazilian government.

  4. 4.

    The New Consensus on Macroeconomics (Blinder 1981, 1998; Taylor 1993, 2000; Allsopp e Vines 2000; Romer 2000) is associated with the growing popularity of inflation targeting and the resulting acceptance that, even where the regime is not adopted, the main instrument of monetary policy is the (basic) interest rate, and no longer the monetary aggregates of some decades ago, influenced by monetarism. The new consensus theoretical core is given by the confluence of monetarism, new classical, and real business cycle theories. The natural rate of unemployment (Friedman 1968) and rational expectations hypothesis are among the two most relevant assumptions shared by this large group of economists. Another fundamental part is the Taylor rule —which holds that the central banks should determine its interest rate aiming at an explicit or implicit inflation target, and at keeping GDP growth near to its potential. We agree with Lavoie that “the only truly new element in the new consensus […] is the rejection of the exogenous supply of money, and the replacement of money growth rule for a real interest rate targeting rule […]” (Lavoie 2004, p. 23).

  5. 5.

    For details on the role of foreign exchange derivative market in Brazil, see Chap. “Foreign Exchange Derivatives and Financial Fragility in Brazil” of this book by Maryse Farhi.

  6. 6.

    According to existing literature (Modenesi and Modenesi 2012): among the main empirical-institutional features of Brazilian economy that compromises the monetary policy transmission, these are noteworthy: (i) nonexistence of a yield curve for sufficiently long maturity periods; (ii) the high share of administered prices in the IPCA; (iii) existence of a perverse cost channel; and (iv) the so-called LFT problem (Modenesi and Modenesi 2012). LFT (Letras Financeiras do Tesouro, in Portuguese) is a special kind of government bonds that are indexed to Selic.

  7. 7.

    Even recognizing that Brazil’s rates of growth in the 1980s were low, one cannot deny that monetary policy has, at least, constituted a relevant hindrance to the reversal of this situation.

  8. 8.

    Administered prices represent around 30% of CPI in Brazil. Many of them are (directly or indirectly) indexed to exchange rate. One should note that not all administrated prices are indexed to past inflation.

  9. 9.

    In the McCarthy (2007) model, inflation is determined by “supply” shocks, “demand” shocks, and the exchange rate.

  10. 10.

    One should conclude, that in both studies, the results showed that exchange rate pass-through was higher during periods of depreciation of the local currency than in periods of appreciation.

  11. 11.

    Under the so-called normal regime, the pass-through to consumer prices was not statistically significant. Comparatively, the expected pass-through under a “crisis” regime is of 10%. “Crisis” periods occurred from 2000 to 2003 and in 2015, years in which the BRL depreciated. The “normal” cycle extends from 2003 to 2014, years of continuous appreciation of the local currency (except for July to November 2008).

  12. 12.

    For instance, Brun-Aguerre et al. (2017), Pollard and Coughlin (2003), Herzberg et al. (2003), Bussiere (2013), Webber (1999), Wickremasinghe and Silvapulle (2004), Campa et al. (2008), Alvarez et al. (2008), Gil-Pareja (2000) and Karoro et al. (2009), estimate asymmetric exchange rate pass-through to import prices. Khundrakpam (2007) employ producer prices. Mihaljek and Klau (2008), Przystupa and Wróbel (2011) and Delatte and Villavicencio (2012) utilize asymmetric exchange rate pass-through to consumer prices. All these papers decompose the exchange rate in appreciations and depreciations.

  13. 13.

    Sometimes it also refers to the speed that exchange rate fluctuations affect prices.

  14. 14.

    According to Goldfajn and Werlang (2000) and Calvo and Reinhart (2000) ERTP is higher for the emerging countries than for developed countries. Additionally, in emerging countries, with currencies placed at the lower end of the currency hierarchy, exchange rate is prone to be more volatile (Paula et al. 2017).

  15. 15.

    “Most recent empirical studies of monetary policy and real economic activity have adopted a vector autoregression (VAR)” (Walsh 2003, 24).

  16. 16.

    For details on the SVAR models used, and the decomposition of the exchange rate series (ER) into ER+ and ER see appendix.

  17. 17.

    Residuals that are not autocorrelated, nor heteroscedastic, and are normally distributed. For residual autocorrelation Portmanteau and Lagrange Multiplier tests were performed. For residual normality, the multivariate Jarque-Bera and White’s test for heteroscedasticity of residuals.

  18. 18.

    The same structural factorization used to calculate impulse response functions was used in variance decomposition.

  19. 19.

    The simulated indexes are a partial analysis that only considers the impact of exchange rate variations on the IPCA for comparative purposes, not considering other factors also important for the dynamics of the Brazilian inflation rate. The upward trend shown by the simulated asymmetric index resembles much more the observed trajectory of actual IPCA.

  20. 20.

    It is necessary to impose \({{K\left( {K + 1} \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{K\left( {K + 1} \right)} 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2}\) restrictions on both matrices A and B to satisfy order condition. The order condition is necessary for identification but may not suffice if rank condition fail. Rubio-Ramirez et al. (2010) discuss rank conditions for identification in SVAR models.

References

  • Allsopp, C., & Vivens, D. (2000). The assessment: Macroeconomic policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 16(4), 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almendra, P., Portugal, M., & Macêdo, G. (2015). Pass-through da taxa de câmbio para a inflação no Brasil: Um estudo econométrico utilizando o filtro de Kalman. 43º Encontro Nacional de Economia (ANPEC). Florianopolis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Álvarez, E., Jaramillo, P., & Selaive, J. (2008). Exchange rate pass-through into import prices: The case of Chile (Working Paper No. 465). Santiago: Banco Central de Chile.

    Google Scholar 

  • Araújo, E., & Modenesi, A. (2010). A Importância do Setor Externo na Evolução do IPCA (1999–2010): uma análise com base em um modelo SVAR. XXXVIII Encontro Nacional de Economia—ANPEC, Salvador.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P., Ferrari, Filho F., & Paula, L. F. (2011). Inflation targeting in Brazil. International Review of Applied Economics, 25(2), 127–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belaisch, A. (2003). Exchange rate pass-through in Brazil (IMF Working Paper 03/141). Washington: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. (1981). Monetarism is obsolete. Challenge, September/October, pp. 35–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blinder A. (1998). A core of macroeconomic beliefs. Challenge, July/August, pp. 36–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • BCB. (2016). Inflation targeting in Brazil. Brazilian Central Bank, Brasília. Available at http://www.bcb.gov.br/pec/metas/InflationTargetingTable.pdf.

  • Brun-Aguerre, R., Fuertes, A., & Greenwood-Nimmo, M. (2017). Heads I win; tails you lose: Asymmetry in exchange rate pass-through into import prices. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 180(2), February, 587–612.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bussiere, M. (2013). Exchange rate pass-through in the G7 economies: The role of nonlinearities and asymmetries. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 75(5), 731–758.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G., & Reinhart, C. (2000). Fixing for your life (NBER Working Papers 8006). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campa, J., & Goldberg, L. (2005). Exchange rate pass-through into imports prices. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 679–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campa, J., Mínguez, J., & Barriel, M. (2008). Non-linear adjustment of import prices in the European Union (Bank of England Working Paper No. 347).

    Google Scholar 

  • Carneiro, D., Monteiro, A., & Wu, T. (2004). Mecanismos não-lineares de repasse cambial para o IPCA. Revista de Economia e Administração, 3(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho, F. (2000–2001). The IMF as crisis manager: An assessment of the strategy in Asia and of its criticisms. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Winter 23(2), 235–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choudhri, E., & Hakura, D. (2006). Exchange rate pass-through to domestic prices: Does the inflationary environment matter? Journal of International Money and Finance, 25(4), 614–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Correa, A. S., & Minella, A. (2010). Nonlinear mechanisms of the exchange rate pass-through: A Phillips curve model with threshold for Brazil. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 64(3), 231–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, P. (2003). Post Keynesian macroeconomic theory. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delatte, A., & Villavicencio, A. (2012). Asymmetric exchange rate pass-through: Evidence from major countries. Journal of Macroeconomics, 34(3), 833–844.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enders, W. (2014). Applied Econometric Time Series. Wiley Series in Probability and Mathematical Statistics. London: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, H., & Baldwin, R. (1986). Marketing bottlenecks and the relationship between exchange rates and prices (Working Paper). Cambridge, MA: Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraga, G., & Couto, S. (2013). O pass-through da taxa de câmbio para índices de preços: uma análise empírica para o Brasil. XVI Encontro de Economia da Região Sul—ANPEC/SUL, Curitiba.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1956). The quantity theory of money—a restatement. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Studies in the quantity theory of money. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1968). The role of monetary policy. The American Economic Review, LVIII(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K., & Klemperer, P. (1989). Exchange rate pass-through when market share matters. American Economic Review, 79(4), 637–654.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gagnon, J., & Ihrig, J. (2004). Monetary policy and exchange rate pass-through. International Journal of Finance & Economics, 9(4), 315–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Pareja, S. (2000). Exchange rates and European countries’ export prices: An empirical test for asymmetries in pricing to market behavior. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 136(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfajn, I., & Werlang, S. (2000). The pass-through from depreciation to inflation: A panel study (Banco Central Do Brasil Working Paper 5). Brasília: Banco Central do Brasil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C., & Yoon, G. (2002). Hidden cointegration (Department of Economics Working Paper No. 02). San Diego: University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzberg, V., Kapetanios, G., & Price G. (2003). Import prices and exchange rate pass through: Theory and evidence from the United Kingdom (Bank of England Working Paper No. 182).

    Google Scholar 

  • IBGE (2016). National system of consumer price indexes. Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, Brasília. Available at http://www.ibge.gov.br/english/estatistica/indicadores/precos/inpc_ipca/defaultinpc.shtm.

  • IMF (2016a). International financial statistics. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C., US. Available at http://data.imf.org.

  • IMF (2016b). World economic outlook. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, US. Available at http://data.imf.org.

  • Karoro, T., Meshach, A., & Cattaneo, N. (2009). Exchange rate pass-through to import prices in South Africa: Is there asymmetry? South African Journal of Economics, 77(3), 380–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khundrakpam, J. (2007). Economic reforms and exchange rate pass-through to domestic prices in India (Bank for International Settlements Working Paper No. 225). Basel, Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1943). International clearing union, 28 Parl. Deb., H. L. (5th ser.), 527–537.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1980). The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes. In D. E. Moggridge (Ed.), Activities 1940–1944. Shaping the Post-war World: The Clearing Union, Vol. 25. London: Macmillan Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kilian, L. (2011). Structural vector autoregressions, CEPR Discussion Papers No. 8515, London, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knetter, M. (1994). Is export price adjustment asymmetric? Evaluating the market share and marketing bottlenecks hypotheses. Journal of International Money and Finance, 13(1), 55–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohlscheen, E. (2010). Emerging floaters: Pass-throughs and (some) new commodity currencies. Journal of International Money and Finance, 29(8), 1580–1595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kregel, J. (2015) Emerging markets and the international financial architecture: a blueprint for reform. Revista de Economia Política 35(2), 285–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1987). Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes. In S. Arndt & J. Richardson (Eds.), Real-financial linkages among open economies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P., & Obstfeld, M. (1997). International economics: Theory and policy (4th ed.). Massachusetts: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, M. (2004). The new consensus on monetary policy seen from a Post Keynesian perspective. In M. Lavoie & M. Seccareccia (Eds.), Central banking in the modern world: Alternative perspectives. Cheltenham: Edward-Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl, H. (2005). New introduction to multiple time series analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marodin, F., & Portugal, M. (2015). Exchange rate pass-through in Brazil: A Markov switching DSGE estimation for the inflation targeting period (2000–2015) (Working Paper PPGE/UFRGS).

    Google Scholar 

  • Marston, R. (1990). Pricing to market in Japanese manufacturing. Journal of International Economics, 29, 217–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy, J. (2007). Pass-through of exchange rates and import prices to domestic inflation in some industrialized economies. Eastern Economic Journal, 33(4), 511–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menezes, G., & Fernandez, R. (2012). Análise do efeito pass-through cambial para a formação dos índices de preços no Brasil (1999–2011). XV Encontro de Economia da Região Sul—ANPEC/ SUL, Porto Alegre, Brazil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mihaljek, D., & Klau, M. (2008). Exchange rate pass-through in emerging market economies: What has changed and why? (Bank for International Settlements Working Paper No. 35). Basel, Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minella, A., Freitas, P., Goldfajn, I., & Muinhos, M. (2003). Inflation targeting in Brazil: Constructing credibility under exchange rate volatility. Journal of International Money and Finance, 22, 1015–1040.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modenesi, A. (2005). Regimes Monetários: teoria e a experiência do real. 1. ed. Barueri (SP). Ed. Manole.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modenesi, A. M., & Araújo, E. (2013). Price stability under inflation targeting in Brazil: An empirical analysis of the monetary policy transmission mechanism based on a VAR model (2000–2008). Investigación Económica, LXXII, 99–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modenesi, A., & Modenesi, R. (2012). Quinze Anos de Rigidez Monetária no Brasil: uma agenda de pesquisa. Revista de Economia Política, 32(3), 389–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modenesi, A., Modenesi, R., & Silva, T. (2017). Brazil’s Macroprudential framework to tackle the great financial crisis: Monetary policy, financial regulation and the banking system. In E. Grivoyannis (Ed.), The new Brazilian economy: Dynamic transitions into the future. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nogueira, R. (2006). Inflation targeting, exchange rate pass-through and ‘fear of floating’. Studies in Economics 0605, Department of Economics, University of Kent.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nogueira, P. (2007). Inflation targeting and exchange rate pass-through. Economia Aplicada, São Paulo, 11(2), 189–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nogueira, V., Mori, R., & Marcal, E. (2012). Transmissão da variação cambial para as taxas de inflação no Brasil: estimação do pass-through através de modelos de vetores autorregressivos estruturais com correção de erros. XL Encontro Nacional de Economia—ANPEC, Porto de Galinhas, Brazil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nonnenberg, M., & Lameiras, M. (2005). Preços das commodities e o IPA. Boletim de Conjuntura, IPEA, No. 69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paula, L., Fritz, B., & Prates, D. (2017). Keynes at the periphery: Currency hierarchy and challenges for economic policy in emerging economies. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollard, P., & Coughlin, C. (2003). Size matters: Asymmetric exchange rate pass-through at the industry level (Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series No. 2003–2029).

    Google Scholar 

  • Przystupa, J., & Wróbel, E. (2011). Asymmetry of the exchange rate pass-through: An exercise on the Polish data. Eastern European Economics, 49(1), 30–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reis, M., Modenesi, A., & Modenesi, R. (2016). The Brazilian economy after the 2008 Global financial crisis: The end of the macroeconomic tripod’s golden age. In H. Cömert & A. McKenzie (Eds.), The global south after the crisis growth, inequality and development in the aftermath of the great recession (pp. 95–118). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, D. (2000). Keynesian macroeconomics without the LM curve. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(2), 149–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubio-Ramirez, J., Waggoner, D., & Zha, T. (2010). Structural vector autoregressions: Theory of Identification and algorithms for Inference. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 665–696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schorderet, Y. (2004). Asymmetric cointegration (Working Paper). Department of Econometrics, University of Geneva, Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, C. & Vernengo, M. (2008). The decline of the exchange rate pass-through in Brazil: Explaining the ‘Fear of Floating’. International Journal of Political Economy, 37(4), 64–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Squeff, G. (2009). Repasse cambial reverso: uma avaliação sobre a relação entre taxa de câmbio e IPCA no Brasil (1999–2007). II Encontro Internacional da Associação Keynesiana Brasileira, Porto Alegre, Brazil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Souza, R., & Alves, A. (2011). Relação entre câmbio e preços no Brasil: aspectos teóricos e evidências empíricas. XXXVIII Encontro Nacional de Economia, ANPEC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Souza, R., Maciel, L., & Pizzinga, A. (2013). State space models for the exchange rate pass-through: Determinants and null/full pass-through hypotheses. Applied Economics, 45(36), 5062–5075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. (2000). Teaching modern macroeconomics at the principles level. American Economic Review, 90(2), 90–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. (2001). The role of the exchange rate in monetary-policy rules. The American Economic Review, 91(2), 263–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernengo, M. (2006). Money and inflation. In P. Arestis & M. Sawyer (Eds.), Handbook of alternative monetary economics. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C. (2003). Monetary theory and policy (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ware, R., & Winter, R. (1988). Forward markets, currency options and the hedging of foreign exchange risk. Journal of International Economics, 25(3), 291–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webber, A. (1999). Newton’s gravity law and import prices in the Asia Pacific. Japan and the World Economy, 12(1), 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wickremasinghe, G., & Silvapulle, P. (2004). Exchange rate pass-through to manufactured import prices: The case of Japan. International Trade, 406006.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andre de Melo Modenesi .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 SVAR Model

Consider a K-dimensional time series \(Y_{t} = \left( {y_{1} ,y_{2} , y_{3} ,y_{4} } \right)^{'}\) where Y t is a SVAR of finite order p of the structural form

$$AY_{t} = v_{0} + B_{1} Y_{t - 1} + \cdots + B_{p} Y_{t - p} + Bu_{t}$$
(1)

where A is a K × K matrix that defines the causal interrelationships among the contemporaneous variables, and u t denotes a mean zero uncorrelated error term (also referred to as structural innovation or structural shock) with a variance-covariance matrix \(E\left( {u_{t} ,u_{t}^{\prime } } \right) =\Sigma _{u}\). Because structural shocks are by definition uncorrelated, \(\Sigma _{u}\) is a diagonal matrix (Kilian 2011).

Equation (1) cannot be estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) since the variables have contemporaneous effects on each other. OLS estimates would suffer from simultaneous equation bias since the regressors and error terms would be correlated (Enders 2014).

In order to allow estimation, it is necessary to derive its reduced form representation. Premultiplication on both sides of Eq. (1) by A −1 allows the reduced form (2) to be obtained.

$$Y_{t} = c_{0} +\Phi _{1} Y_{t - 1} +\Phi _{2} Y_{t - 2} + \cdots +\Phi _{p} Y_{t - p} + e_{t}$$
(2)

Where \(c_{0} = A^{ - 1} v_{0} ;\quad\Phi _{i} = A^{ - 1} B_{i} ;\quad Ae_{t} = Bu_{t}\).

Standard OLS method obtains consistent estimates of the reduced form (2) parameters \(\Phi _{i}\), the reduced form errors e t and their covariance matrix \(E\left( {e_{t} e_{t}^{\prime } } \right) =\Sigma _{e}\) (Lütkepohl 2005).

However, the reduced form errors are correlated. Only in the special case where there are no contemporaneous effects among variables (i.e., matrix A elements, \(a_{ij} (i \ne j)\), equals zero) the shocks will be uncorrelated.

It is possible, however, to recover the structural VAR coefficients and analyze how Y t respond to structural shocks in u t , from the estimates of the model in reduced form since, by construction, \(Ae_{t} = Bu_{t}\). Hence, the variance of e t is

$$\Sigma _{e} = A^{ - 1} B\Sigma _{u} B^{\prime } A^{{ - 1^{\prime } }}$$
(3)

\(\Sigma _{e}\) can be consistently estimated from the reduced form by OLS, and the system can be solved for the unknown parameters provided that the number of unknown parameters do not exceed the number of equations. This involves imposing restrictions on matrix A. Usually, the most common approach is to impose a ij  = 0 restrictions (Kilian 2011).Footnote 20

The assumption a ij  = 0 means that yj does not have a contemporaneous effect on yi. The imposition of different restrictions will result in different impulse response functions depending on the correlation between errors in the reduced form. Only if all reduced form errors are uncorrelated impulse response functions will be the same regardless of the restrictions imposed.

1.1.1 Asymmetry

One possible approach to investigate the existence of asymmetric effects of x t on y t is to decompose the variable x t into two new series: \(x_{t}^{ + }\) of its positive variations and \(x_{t}^{ - }\) of the negative variations.

Based on Schorderet (2004) and Granger and Yoon (2002) method, a time series can be decomposed as follows:

$$x_{t} = x_{0} + x_{t}^{ + } + x_{t}^{ - }$$
(4)

Where

$$x_{t}^{ + } = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{t} {\theta_{i} } (\Delta x_{i} );\quad \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\theta_{i} = 1 \,{\text{se}}\,\Delta x_{i} > 0,} \hfill \\ {0,\,{\text{otherwise}}. } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(5)
$$x_{t}^{ - } = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{t} {\theta_{i}^{*} } (\Delta x_{i} );\quad \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { \theta_{i}^{*} = 1\,{\text{se}}\,\Delta x_{i} < 0, } \hfill \\ {0,\,{\text{otherwise}}. } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(6)

Such as that, x t value, for all t, is equal to its initial value (x 0) plus the sum of all its positive and negative variations up to t.

In this way, we have first difference of \(x_{t}^{ + }\) and \(x_{t}^{ - }\) series:

$$dx_{t}^{ + } = \theta_{i} (\Delta x_{i} );\quad \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { \theta_{i} = 1 \,{\text{se}} \,\Delta x_{i} > 0, } \hfill \\ {0,\, {\text{otherwise}}. } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(7)
$$dx_{t}^{ - } = \theta_{i}^{*} (\Delta x_{i} );\quad \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { \theta_{i}^{*} = 1\,{\text{se}}\,\Delta x_{i} < 0, } \hfill \\ {0,\,{\text{otherwise}}. } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(8)

The decomposition in form (5) and (6) is known in literature as decomposition by cumulative variations whereas the form in (7) and (8) is known as period-to-period variations.

Series decomposed by cumulative variations have unit root and cointegrate and are used in the estimation of error correction models (ECM) and its multivariate form vector error correction (VEC).

For purpose of this chapter, that estimates a model with the stationary variables in first difference, the most adequate decomposition, that was used, is the period-to-period decomposition.

1.1.2 Exchange Rate Pass-Through

The exchange rate pass-through can be calculated from impulse response functions estimated by the SVAR model. This method was used by McCarthy (2007) to calculate the exchange rate pass-through for several industrialized countries and by Belaisch (2003) and Araújo and Modenesi (2010) for Brazil.

$$R_{t,t + j} = \left( {\frac{{\Sigma {\kern 1pt} \Delta {\text{CPI}}_{t,t + j} }}{{\Sigma {\kern 1pt} \Delta {\text{ER}}_{t,t + j} }}} \right)\, \cdot \,100$$
(9)

Where ΔCPI is consumer price index variations and ΔER exchange rate variations.

1.1.3 Wald Coefficient Restriction Test

Wald coefficient restriction tests were performed in asymmetric models to test the hypothesis that the coefficients relative to exchange rate positive variations are statistically different from the negative variations.

The test was performed under two different null hypothesis specifications:

H 0 (A):

Null hypothesis that the sum of the coefficients of \(x^{ + }\) lags is equal to the sum of the coefficients of \(x^{ - }\) lags.

H 0 (B):

Null hypothesis that the lag coefficient i of y + is equal to the lag coefficient i of \(y^{ - }\) for all lags.

To illustrate, generically, a two lags model, SVAR (2), and three variables, \(Y_{t} = \left( {y_{1}^{ + } ,y_{1}^{ - } ,y_{2} } \right)^{'}\), where \(y_{1}^{ + }\) and \(y_{1}^{ - }\) are period-to-period decompositions of \(y_{1}\)

In reduced form:

$$Y_{t} = c_{0} +\Phi _{1} Y_{t - 1} +\Phi _{2} Y_{t - 2} + e_{t}$$
(10)

Can be written in the form

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {y_{{1_{t} }}^{ + } = c_{1} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ + } + c_{2} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ + } + c_{3} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ - } + c_{4} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ - } + c_{5} y_{{2_{t - 1} }} + c_{6} \Delta y_{{2_{t - 2} }} + c_{7} } \hfill \\ {y_{{1_{t} }}^{ - } = c_{8} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ + } + c_{9} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ + } + c_{10} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ - } + c_{11} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ - } + c_{12} y_{{2_{t - 1} }} + c_{13} \Delta y_{{2_{t - 2} }} + c_{14} } \hfill \\ {y_{{2_{t} }} = c_{15} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ + } + c_{16} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ + } + c_{17} y_{{1_{t - 1} }}^{ - } + c_{18} y_{{1_{t - 2} }}^{ - } + c_{19} y_{{2_{t - 1} }} + c_{20} \Delta y_{{2_{t - 2} }} + c_{21} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$

The Wald test was then calculated under H 0 with two different specifications

H 0 (A):

$$H_{0} :c_{1} + c_{2} = c_{3} + c_{4} \,{\text{and}}\, c_{8} + c_{9} = c_{10} + c_{11} \, {\text{and}}\, c_{15} + c_{16} = c_{17} + c_{18 }$$

H 0 (B):

$$H_{0} :c_{1} = c_{3} \,{\text{and}}\, c_{2} = c_{4} \,e\, c_{8} = c_{10} \,{\text{and}}\, c_{9} = c_{11} \,{\text{and}}\, c_{15} = c_{17} \, e\, c_{16} = c_{18 }$$

Under H 0, the Wald statistic is asymptotically distributed as a χ 2(q), where q is the number of linear restrictions.

Wald test statistics reject the null hypothesis that coefficients are equal at conventional significance levels. Under the null hypothesis A, the test statistic was 8.38 (0.08 p-value). Under the null hypothesis B, test statistic was 16.57 (0.03 p-value). Therefore, results indicate the existence of asymmetry, that is, that exchange rate devaluations have different effects on inflation than exchange rate appreciations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

de Melo Modenesi, A., Luporini, V., Pimentel, D. (2017). Asymmetric Exchange Rate Pass-Through: Evidence, Inflation Dynamics and Policy Implications for Brazil (1999–2016). In: Arestis, P., Troncoso Baltar, C., Prates, D. (eds) The Brazilian Economy since the Great Financial Crisis of 2007/2008. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-64885-9_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-64885-9_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-64884-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-64885-9

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics