Skip to main content

A Critical Approach to Teaching Financial Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Post-Crash Economics
  • 575 Accesses

Abstract

Finance is usually perceived as a set of quantitative techniques aimed at maximising profit and minimising risk. In this respect then, the quality of teaching financial economics is considered to be proportional to the number of techniques students are able to master. This chapter argues that finance can be taught by using a new approach, namely, the Teaching with Historical Perspectives. By using a historical perspective, this approach encourages a deeper understanding of financial theory. The chapter will provide some specific examples to illustrate the above points. The chapter concludes by reflecting on the teaching practice of mainstream finance and suggests that this can provide an opportunity to develop a critical perspective towards financial theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1986). Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Financial Economics, 17(2), 223–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, P. L. (1992). Capital ideas: The improbable origins of modern wall street. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, F., Jensen, M. C., & Scholes, M. (1972). The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests. In M. C. Jensen (Ed.), Studies in the theory of capital markets. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, B. S. (1994). Bloom’s taxonomy: A forty-year retrospective. In L. W. Anderson & L. A. Sosniak (Eds.), Yearbook of the National Society for the Study of Education. Chicago: National Society for the Study of Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breeden, D. (1979). An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities. Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 265–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, N., Roll, R., & Ross, S. (1986). Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business, 59(3), 383–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chopra, N., Lakonishok, J., & Ritter, J. R. (1992). Measuring abnormal performance: Do stocks overreact? Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 235–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, J., & Kaul, G. (1988). Time-variation in expected returns. Journal of Business, 61(4), 409–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cootner, P. H. (1964). The random character of stock market prices. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowles, A. (1933). Can stock market forecasters forecast? Econometrica, 1(3), 309–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowles, A. (1960). A revision of previous conclusions regarding stock price behavior. Econometrica, 28(4), 909–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crotty, J. (2013). The realism of assumptions does matter: Why Keynes–Minsky theory must replace efficient market theory as the guide to financial regulation policy. In G. Epstein & M. Wolfson (Eds.), Oxford handbook of the political economy of financial crises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Douglas, G. W. (1969). Risk in the equity markets: An empirical appraisal of market efficiency. Yale Economic Essays, 9(1), 3–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K., Cotter, J., Humphrey, C., & Woods, M. (2008). How unlucky is 25-sigma? arXiv preprint: 1103.5672. Retrieved April 10, 2017, from http://arxiv.org/ftp/arxiv/papers/1103/1103.5672.pdf

  • Epstein, G. A. (Ed.). (2005). Financialization and the world economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1970a). Multiperiod consumption-investment decisions. The American Economic Review, 60, 163–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1970b). Efficient capital market: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the return on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & MacBeth, J. (1973). Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 607–636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Financial Times. (2007, August 14). Goldman pays the price of being big.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. C. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groenewegen, J. (2007). Teaching pluralism in economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakansson, N. (1974). Convergence in multiperiod portfolio choice. Journal of Financial Economics, 1, 201–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton, J., & Lucas, D. (2000). Portfolio choice and asset prices: The importance of entrepreneurial risk. Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1163–1198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan, R., & Wang, Z. (1996). The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Finance, 51(1), 3–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jegadeesh, N., & Titman, S. (1993). Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stick market efficiency. Journal of Finance, 48(1), 65–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, F. (2008). The construction of the canonical history of financial economics. History of Political Economy, 40(2), 213–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, M. G. (1953). The analysis of economic time-series—Part 1: Prices. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 116, 11–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1930). Treatise of money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1973). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kilborn, P. T. (1988). “Fresh water” economists gain. New York Times, 23 July. Retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/1988/07/23/business/fresh-water-economists-gain.html?pagewanted¼all&src¼pm

  • Krugman, P. (2009). How did economists get it so wrong? New York Times, 6 September. Retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/06/magazine/06Economic-t.html?pagewanted¼all

  • Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1995). Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance, 50(5), 541–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, M. (1999). The credit-led supply of deposits and the demand for money: Kaldor’s reflux mechanism as previously endorsed by Joan Robinson. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(1), 103–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lintner, J. (1965). Security prices, risk and maximal gains from diversification. Journal of Finance, 20(4), 587–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lippert, J. (2008). John Lippert on the Chicago School. Bloomberg, 23 December. Retrieved from http://delong.typepad.com/egregious_moderation/2008/12/john-lippert-on-the-chicago-school.html

  • Lo, A. W., & Mackinlay, A. G. (1988). Stock market prices do not follow random walk: Evidence from a simple specification test. Review of Financial Studies, 1(1), 41–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1978). Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica, 46(6), 1429–1445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malkiel, B. G. (1995). Returns from investing in equity mutual funds 1971 to 1991. Journal of Finance, 50(2), 549–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayers, D. (1972). Nonmarketable assets and capital market equilibrium under uncertainty. In M. C. Jensen (Ed.), Studies in the theory of capital markets. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLeay, M., Radia, A., & Thoms, R. (2014). Money creation in the modern economy. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin. First quarter, 15–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1992). Continuous-time finance. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, M. H., & Scholes, M. (1972). Rates of return in relation to risk: A re-examination of some recent findings. In M. C. Jensen (Ed.), Studies in the theory of capital markets. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica, 34(4), 768–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. (1977). A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests part I: On past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics, 4(2), 129–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (1976). Return, risk and arbitrage. In I. Friend & J. Bicksler (Eds.), Risk and return in finance. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, W. F. (1967). A simplified model of portfolio analysis. Management Science, 13, 277–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheikh, A. Z., & Qiao, H. (2009). Non-normality of market returns: A framework for asset-allocation decision-making. New York: J.P. Morgan Asset Management.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soros, G. (2009). The crash of 2008 and what it means: The new paradigm for financial markets. New York: Perseus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stambaugh, R. F. (1982). On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two-parameter model: A sensitivity analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 10(3), 237–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavasci, D., & Ventimiglia, L. (2018). Teaching the history of economic thought: Integrating historical perspectives into modern economics. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. (1958). Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies, 25, 65–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Working, H. (1956). New ideas and methods for price research. Journal of Farm Economics, 38, 1427–1436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ventimiglia, L. (2018). A Critical Approach to Teaching Financial Economics. In: Feraboli, O., Morelli, C. (eds) Post-Crash Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-65855-1_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-65855-1_10

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-65854-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-65855-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics