Skip to main content

State Aid for Newspapers: First Theoretical Disputes

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
State Aid for Newspapers

Part of the book series: Media Business and Innovation ((MEDIA))

Abstract

If one first lays aside any definitional problems—the term state aid is used within the European Union, and the term subsidies the standard expression of the World Trade Organization, while the OECD prefers to use the word support—state aid, at a very fundamental level, commonly refers to a cash payment or financial assistance from a government or other public authority to a person or company. State aid for newspapers, more particularly, usually serves two main purposes: They should reduce a person’s or company’s cost of producing and bringing a commodity to market, and, secondly, by reducing the price of the commodity, should increase its consumption beyond what competitive market forces would provide for.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Ross argued that to raise welfare of an individual at the lowest possible cost, cash grants are more efficient than subsidies to the consumption of specific commodities (Ross 1988). Equally, Peltzman (1973) looked into education subsidies and found that an in-kind subsidy, such as below-cost education provided by state universities, replaces more private consumption of the subsidized good than an equivalent money subsidy, such as a scholarship.

  2. 2.

    For an overview on financial issues of media management, see, Rizzuto (2006), Ozanich (2006), and Picard (2011).

  3. 3.

    The term subsidy may also refer to assistance granted by other institutions than government, such as individuals or private nongovernmental institutions, although this is more commonly described as charity.

  4. 4.

    Picard (1982, pp. 4–5).

  5. 5.

    Timo Toivonen, researcher at Turku School of Economics in Finland, calculated the value of VAT reductions in three nations and found that VAT reductions for circulation sales in 2010 amounted for by 525 million euros in Germany, 250 million euros in Italy, and 748 million euros in the UK [Toivonen, as cited in Nielsen and Linnebank (2011), pp. 31–32].

  6. 6.

    Gordon Tullock, who originated the idea in 1967, was first to point to the negative externalities through rent-seeking behavior (Tullock 1967).

  7. 7.

    This duopoly game model is inspired by the model of competition used in economics, named after the French mathematician Joseph Louis François Bertrand (1822–1900).

  8. 8.

    If Newspaper B chooses a low price its payoffs is calculated as follows: (1 × 100,000 euros) − (1 × 100,000 euros) = 0. In this competitive pricing scenario, Newspaper A would have to expect the same zero profit payoff in this equilibrium.

  9. 9.

    Of course, this is a stark simplification as, under such conditions, numerous external factors influencing demand, such as population and tastes, and the quality of the newspaper from the point of view of the reader are assumed away.

  10. 10.

    On the upside, incomplete information about vertical quality signaled via price would soften price competition (Daughety and Reinganum 2008).

  11. 11.

    In economic theory, the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics describes an idealized system of equilibrium conditions to efficiently coordinate economic activity (Pareto 1971/1927). Markets that do not achieve this Pareto optimality are said to result in market failure.

  12. 12.

    Arthur Cecil Pigou has been called the father of the market failure paradigm. Indeed, he argued that “in any industry, where there is reason to believe that the free play of self-interest will cause an amount of resources to be invested different from the amount that is required in the best interests of the national dividend, there is a prima facie case for public intervention” (1932, p. 331). He suggested that taxes could be used when external diseconomies are present and that the existence of external economies would warrant the use of subsidies.

  13. 13.

    A PED is easily calculated. For example, if the price of a daily newspaper increases from 1.00 euros to 1.20 euros and the daily sales fall from 500,000 to 250,000, the PED will be –50 % + 20 % = (−) 2.5. The negative sign indicates that P and Q are inversely related, which we would expect for most price/demand relationships. This is significant because the newspaper supplier can calculate or estimate how revenue will be affected by the change in price. In this case, revenue at 1.00 euros is 500,000 euros (1 euros × 500,000) but falls to 300,000 euros after the price rise (1.20 euros × 250,000).

  14. 14.

    If, on the information readily available to them, readers can discriminate between prices but are not able to discover quality and thus will not rationally price trade-off against quality, publishers with high-quality newspapers will be driven out of the market, and there will be a general lowering of standards (Akerlof 1970).

  15. 15.

    Such means are, for example signaling, whereby information is distributed by sellers to buyers by way of quality monitoring systems, whereas “screening” refers to the buyers acquiring information by the help of consumer protection groups. The aim is identical: removing the asymmetry in information.

  16. 16.

    Paul Samuelson (1954) and Richard A. Musgrave (1959) and others consolidated the market failure paradigm in the 1950s. However, this paradigm was contested since its inception.

  17. 17.

    The term was coined in the 1950s to refer to economists teaching in the Economics Department at the University of Chicago, such as Frank Knight, Ronald Coase, and Milton Friedman.

References

  • Ahrend, R. (2002, February). Press freedom, human capital and corruption (DELTA Working Paper No. 2002-11). Accessed January 3, 2013, from http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.620102

  • Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for lemons. Qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain, J. S. (1956). Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Cave, M. (1999). Understanding regulation. Theory, strategy, and practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., Cave, M., & Lodge, M. (Eds.). (2010). The oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, 351–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W., & Willig, R. (1981). Fixed costs, sunk costs, entry barriers and sustainability of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96, 405–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, J. L. F. (1883). Théorie Mathématique de la Richesse Sociale, Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses. Journal de Savants, 67, 499–508.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. D., & Romano, R. E. (1993). Pricing decisions of the newspaper monopolist. Southern Economic Journal, 54, 721–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti, A., & Weder, B. (2003). A free press is bad news for corruption. Journal of Public Economics, 87(7), 1801–1824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., & Tullock, G. (Eds.). (1980). Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael, F. (2005). A guide to game theory. Hallow, England: Pearson Education Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, E. H. (1962/1933). The theory of monopolistic competition (8th ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1974). The market for goods and the market for ideas. American Economic Review, 64, 384–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. (Eds.). (2008). 40 years of rent-seeking research. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1988). The theory of market failure. A critical examination. Fairfax, VA: George Mason University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T., & Crampton, E. (2002). Market failure or success. The new debate. Cheltenham: Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture. A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daughety, A. F., & Reinganum, J. R. (2008). Imperfect competition and quality signaling. RAND Journal of Economics, 39(1), 163–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1982). Barriers to entry. The American Economic Review, 72(1), 47–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuldenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabszewicz, J. J., Laussel, D., & Sonnac, N. (2005). Press industry and the political differentiation of newspapers. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 4(3), 317–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehlbach, S., & Sonin, K. (2011). Government control of the media. Accessed April 3, 2013, from http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1315882

  • Gustafsson, K. E. (1993). Government policies to reduce newspaper entry barriers. The Journal of Media Economics, 6(1), 37–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hantke-Domas, M. (2003). The public interest theory of regulation: Non-existence or misinterpretation. European Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 165–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heinrich, J. (1984). Marktzutritt als Systemelement des Wettbewerbs. In G. G. Kopper & G. Gerd (Eds.), Marktzutritt bei Tageszeitungen—Zur Sicherung von Meinungsvielfalt durch Wettbewerb (pp. 75–86). München: Saur.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jung, J. (2003). Measuring the financial health of media firms: The bigger, the better? The International Journal of Media Management, 5(4), 237–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. E. (1986). The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39(1), 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. E., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 1095–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, S. (1992). The financial commitment approach to news media competition. Journal of Media Economics, 5(2), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, S. (1993). Understanding & serving readers: The problems of fuzzy market structure. Newspaper Research Journal, 14(2), 55–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, S. (2004). Fuzzy market structure and differentiation: One size does not fit all. In R. G. Picard (Ed.), Strategic responses to media market changes (pp. 83–95). Jonköping, Sweden: Media Management and Transformation Centre.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J., & Tirole, J. (1991). The politics of government decision-making: A theory of regulatory capture. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1089–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindstedt, C., & Naurin, D. (2005). Transparency and corruption. The conditional significance of a free press (QOG Working Paper Series: 5). Göteborg University. Accessed April 3, 2013, from http://www.qog.pol.gu.se/digitalAssets/1350/1350633_2005_5-lindstedt_naurin.pdf

  • Ludwig, J. (2000). The essential economic problem of the media: Working between market failure and cross-financing. Journal of Media Economics, 13(3), 187–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, R. W. (2008). The political economy of the media. Enduring issues, emerging dilemmas. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murschetz, P. (2008). Theory of market failure. In C. Scholz, & U. Eisenbeis (Eds.), Looking to the future of modern media management. Changes—Challenges—Opportunities (IMMAA Report 2007/2008, pp. 59–65). Lisbon: MediaXXI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. A. (1959). The theory of public finance. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. A. (2008). Merit goods. In S. N. Durlauf, & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The new palgrave dictionary of economics (2nd ed). London: Palgrave Macmillan (April 9, 2013). Accessed 3 January 2013, from http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000152, doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1089

  • Musgrave, R. A., & Peacock, A. T. (1958). Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance, 39, 575–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C. (2000). The capital structure. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 81–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1950). Equilibrium points in n-person games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 36(1), 48–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen, R. K., & Linnebank, G. (2011). Public support for the media: A six-country overview of direct and indirect subsidies. Oxford: Reuters Institute for the Study of Journalism.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD—Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. (2010). Roundtable on competition, state aids and subsidies. DAF/COMP/GF(2010)5. Accessed March 10, 2011, from http://www.oecd.org

  • Office of Fair Trading—OFT. (2004). Public subsidies. A report by the Office of Fair Trading, prepared by Frontier Economics, OFT London (OFT750).

    Google Scholar 

  • Office of Fair Trading—OFT. (2006). UK guidance on how to assess the competition effects of subsidies. A report by the Office of Fair Trading, prepared by Nera Economic Consulting, London (OFT 829 by Nera Economic Consulting).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozanich, G. W. (2006). Media finance and evaluation. In A. B. Albarran, S. M. Chan-Olmsted, & M. O. Wirth (Eds.), Handbook of media management and economics (pp. 601–621). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. (1971/1927). Manual of political economy. (1971 translation of 1927 edition). New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1973). The effect of government subsidies-in-kind on private expenditures: The case of higher education. Journal of Political Economy, 81(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pfeffer, G., & Salancik, G. (1978). The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (1982). State intervention in U.S. Press Economics. Gazette, 30, 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (1985). Patterns of state intervention in Western Press Economics. Journalism Quarterly, 62, 3–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (1991, October 4–5). Competitive effects of state press policies. An analytical framework for policy proposals, paper presented to the ‘political economy vs. media economics’ workshop of the economy and future of print media research program, University of Salzburg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (2004). Commercialism and newspaper quality. Newspaper Research Journal, 25(1), 54–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (2006). Issues and challenges in the provision of press subsidies. In I. Fernandez Alonso, M. de Moragas, J. J. Blasco Gil, & N. Almiron (Eds.), Press subsidies in Europe (pp. 211–220). Barcelona: Generalitat de Catalunya.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (2008). Subsidies for the Media. In W. Donsbach (Ed.), The international encyclopedia of communication (pp. 4891–4894). Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G. (2011). the economics and financing of media companies (2nd ed.). New York: Fordham University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. G., & Brody, J. H. (1997). The newspaper publishing industry. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1932/1920). The economics of welfare (4th ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A., & Strömberg, D. (2011). The political economy of mass media. London: Mimeo, London School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmusen, E. (2007). Games and information: An introduction to game theory (4th ed.). Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reddaway, W. B. (1963). The economics of newspapers. The Economic Journal, 73, 201–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reder, M. W. (1982). Chicago economics: permanence and change. Journal of Economic Literature, 20(1), 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzuto, R. J. (2006). Issues in financial management. In A. B. Albarran, S. M. Chan-Olmsted, & M. O. Wirth (Eds.), Handbook of media management and economics (pp. 145–161). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1933). The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990–1029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roson, R. (2005). Two-sided markets: A tentative survey. Review of Network Economics, 4(2), 142–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, T. W. (1988). On the relative efficiency of cash transfers and subsidies (Working Paper in Economics E-88-20). The Hoover Institution, Stanford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosse, J. N. (1967). Daily newspapers, monopolistic competition, and economies of scale. American Economic Review, 57, 522–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seabright, P., & von Hagen, J. (2007). The economic regulation of broadcasting markets. Evolving technology and challenges for policy. Cambridge, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Steenblik, R. P. (1990). A subsidy primer. Accessed September 8, 2012, from http://www.globalsubsidies.org/subsidy-primer/ASubsidyPrimer.php

  • Steenblik, R. P. (2003). Subsidy measurement and classification: Developing a common framework. In OECD (Ed.), Environmentally harmful subsidies: Policy issues and challenges (pp. 101–141). Paris: OECD Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1968). Barrier to entry, economies of scale, and firm size. In G. J. Stigler (Ed.), The organization of industry (pp. 67–70). Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1988). Chicago studies in political economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1989). On the economic role of the state. In A. Heertje (Ed.), The economic role of the state (pp. 9–85). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strömberg, D. (2004). Mass media competition, political competition, and public policy. Review of Economic Studies, 71, 265–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Truffy, V. (2011). Aides à la presse: 1 milliard d’euros pour la presse papier, 20 millions pour Internet. Accessed December 12, 2012, from http://www.mediapart.fr/journal/economie/110110/aides-la-presse-1-milliard-deuros-pour-la-presse-papier-20-millions-pour-int

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(June), 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). Rent seeking. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The new palgrave: A dictionary of economics (Vol. 4, pp. 147–149). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Bulletin, 76, 31–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vining, A. R. (2003). Internal market failure: A framework for diagnosing firm inefficiency. Journal of Management Studies, 40(2), 431–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker, C. C. (1980). Barriers to entry. A theoretical treatment. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Waterman, D. (1991). Diversity and quality of information products in a monopolistically competitive industry. Information Economics and Policy, 4, 291–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction cost economics. The governance of contractual relations. Journal of law and Economics, 22, 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zaller, J. (1999). Market competition and news quality. Paper prepared for presentation at the 1999 annual meetings of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, GA. Accessed November 5, 2012, from http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/polisci/faculty/zaller/News%20quality%20paper.PDF

  • Zeithaml, V. A. (1988). Consumer perceptions of price, quality, and value: A means-end model and synthesis of evidence. Journal of Marketing, 52(3), 2–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zerbe, R. O., Jr., & McCurdy, H. E. (1999). The failure of market failure. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 18, 558–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul Murschetz .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Murschetz, P. (2013). State Aid for Newspapers: First Theoretical Disputes. In: Murschetz, P. (eds) State Aid for Newspapers. Media Business and Innovation. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-35691-9_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics