Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 428))

Abstract

We have seen in Part 1 of this book that one of MM’s strengths is its interpretable ‘steady state’; namely, a balanced growth path. The economics of balanced growth was worked out in the ‘fifties and ‘sixties in terms of single-sector growth models (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956; Meade, 1961). One conundrum which had to be solved in this literature was how to treat technological change. It turns out that only relatively specialized treatments of technological change are simultaneously consistent with both the existence of a balanced growth path and with the stylized facts characterizing modern economies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 74.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. The notation used in sections 5.2 and 5.3 is self-contained. Readers familiar with elementary ideas about technology in production economics may prefer to skip section 5.2.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Hicks-neutral and Harrod-neutral technical change are defined below.

    Google Scholar 

  3. There is an exceptional case (the Cobb-Douglas production function, (5.2.1)) in which Harrod neutrality and Hicks neutrality are equivalent — see Exercise 5.3 below. In the exceptional Cobb-Douglas case, the factor shares remain stationary over time irrespective of the time rates of improvement in the marginal productivities of the factors.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Thus we have established the third item listed under (ii) above, again conditional on the constancy of the capital-output ratio.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Of course, we have argued (somewhat loosely) from a closed-economy one sector model. Nevertheless, the results are valid in MM.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Because export demand schedules in MM slope downwards, the terms of trade vary endogenously. It follows that to keep K/Y fixed it is necessary to sterilize endogenous changes in the terms of trade by making the foreign demand curves shift outwards during the steady state at the domestic economy’s natural rate of growth γ.

    Google Scholar 

  7. This very low estimate of (3 was regarded as requiring further research (Murphy 1992a, p. II-26 (04/05/92). (In comparing this estimate with others, it should be kept in mind, however, that MM measures labour input in persons, not in person-hours.) Indeed, in more recent versions of MM, the estimated value of ß is higher, as it was in earlier versions of the model — 0.81 per cent per annum is quoted in Murphy (1992b, p. 190).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1995 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Powell, A.A., Murphy, C.W. (1995). Wage Behaviour. In: Inside a Modern Macroeconometric Model. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 428. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-00771-6_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-00771-6_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-60027-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-00771-6

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics