Skip to main content

The Moral Science of Heterogeneous Economic Interaction in Face of Complexity

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Complexities of Production and Interacting Human Behaviour
  • 583 Accesses

Abstract

The principles of political economy, particularly those of the Anglo-Saxon origin, were kinds of utilitarian-based moral philosophy. In this sense, the idea of individualistic rational utility is the essential ontological factor of empiricism to generate the source of all human behaviour in the economic system. Thus, many economists have so far been inclined to indulge in an individualistic utility-based prediction, almost everywhere that human nature matters. While the Schumpeterian epistemological view of the continental idealisms is construed as the triangular theoretical layers of statics, dynamics, and sociodynamics. Without any modification of the ontological–epistemological constructs in economics, we can no longer capture the essence of the rapidly salient evolution of complex economic systems in the modern times.

Reprinted from Dynamisches Denken und Handeln. Philosophie und Wissenschaft in einer komplexen Welt. Festschrift für Klaus Mainzer zum 60. Geburtstag. Aruka, Y., The Moral of Heterogeneous Economic Interaction in the Face of Complexity, 171–183 (2007). With kind permission from Hirzel Verlag, Stuttgart.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    As jump-started by Nelson and Winter’s book, evolutionary economics promptly gained popularity all over the world at the end of the last century. See Nelson and Winter (1982).

  2. 2.

    Arthur depicted this capitalism vividly. Casino capitalism should bring on the “winner-take-all society” if we focus on the distribution side. See Frank and Cook (1995).

  3. 3.

    These particular rationalities are examined in some detail and their failures are argued in Aruka (2006).

  4. 4.

    Such a social transition rate as generating solidarity will be operated in the master equation of the social process. According to the steps of the modelling procedure by Weidlich, we will need a set of various personal attitudes in order to set out the social configuration in our model. When we sketch this configuration, we also need the concept of strength and direction of preference, as being touched later. In particular, direction may be argued as a trend of the social configuration. See Weidlich (2000, Sect. 3.2).

  5. 5.

    In addition to such a state transition, we will use the information on many attributes of the individual like age, gender, income to refine an actual utility function: “The analyst has to identify those that are likely to explain the choice of the individual. There is no automatic process to perform this identification. The knowledge of the actual application and the data availability plays an important role in this process”. Bierlaire (1997, p.4).

  6. 6.

    Here i is omitted for simplicity.

  7. 7.

    We use the scaled preferences such as \( \mathop {\hat{U}}\nolimits (x|\,y;t): = U(x|\,y;t) - {\rm ln}\sum\limits_{x^\prime} \,{e^{U(x^\prime|\,y;t)}}. \)

  8. 8.

    See Sects. 9.1–9.4 in Weidlich (2000).

  9. 9.

    We define a Markov chain \( {X_t} \) on the state space \( S \) which dynamically describes a flux of probabilities. In a state \( j \) at time \( t \), we can imagine a probability \( {P_j}(t) = { \Pr }({X_t} = j) \). We suppose that there are a number of independent agents, each of whom is in one of finite microeconomic states, and its state evolves according to the master equation

    $$ \frac{{d{P_j}(t)}}{{dt}} = \sum\limits_{k \ne j} \,[{P_k}(t){w_{kj}} - {w_{jk}}{P_j}(t)]\ \rm for\ j \in S, $$

    where \( {w_{kj}} \) denotes the transition rates from state \( j \) to state \( k \), or the in-flow rates, and \( {w_{jk}} \) the rates from \( k \) to \( j \), the out-flow rates.

  10. 10.

    The applications of this method are strenuously developed by Aoki (2002), for instance.

  11. 11.

    If we had this critical situation, we would have a kind of entropy maximization.

  12. 12.

    The rational postulates on individualistic behaviour will not necessarily guarantee selfishness of the result of choice. Bowles and Gintis ask in the following manner: “Is cooperation, then, just an expression of self-interest? Do other-regarding preferences such as a reciprocity and altruism play no role in the explanation of human cooperation? The answer hinges on whether most forms of cooperation are altruistic [in society] or mutualistic [in biology]?” (Bowles and Gintis 2005, p. 22).

  13. 13.

    It is noted that Akiyama smartly defined the class of games as dependent games such as Avatamsaka games. See Akiyama and Aruka (2006).

  14. 14.

    See the full text of Mozi (Chinese and English) at http://chinese.dsturgeon.net/text.pl?node=101&if=en

References

  • Akiyama E, Aruka Y (2006) Evolution of reciprocal cooperation in the Avatamsaka game. In: Namatame A, Kaizoji T, Aruka Y (eds) The complex networks of economic interactions: essays in agent-based economics and econophysics. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 307–320

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, Thisse J-F (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (2002) Modeling aggregate behavior and fluctuations in economics: stochastic views of interacting agents. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M, Yoshikawa H (2006) Reconstructing macroeconomics: a perspective from statistical physics and combinatorial stochastic processes. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, NY

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur WB (1996) Increasing returns and the new world of business. Harvard Bus Rev 74:100–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Aruka Y (2001) Avatamsaka game structure and experiment on the Web. In: Aruka Y (ed) Evolutionary controversies in economics. Springer, Tokyo, pp 115–132

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Aruka Y (2003) The complex adaptive processes in economics by heterogeneous interacting agents. In: Russian Academy of Sciences: Institute of Economics and Central Economics and Mathematics Institute (ed) Economic transformation and evolutionary theory of J. Schumpeter. Institute of economics RAS, Moscow, pp 265–285

    Google Scholar 

  • Aruka Y (2006) Evolution der Sittenlehre über Wirtschaftliche Rationalität im Komplexen Sozialsystem. Symposium zur Gründung einer Deutsch-Japanischen Akadmie für integrative Wissenschaft

    Google Scholar 

  • Asano Y (1998) Mozi. Kodansha, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bierlaire M (1997) Discrete choice models, (mimeo) (http://web.mit.edu/mbi/www/michel.html)

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2005) Can self-interest explain cooperation? Evol Inst Econ Rev 2(1):21–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank R, Cook P (1995) The winner-take-all society. Free, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Helbing D (1995) Quantitative sociodynamics: stochastic methods and models of social interaction processes. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps DM (1990) A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce R (1959) Individual choice behavior: a theoretical analysis. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainzer K (2005) Was sind komplexe Systeme? In: Symposium zur Gründung einer Deutsch-Japanischen Akadmie für integrative Wissenschaft, J.H. Röll Verlag, pp 37–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Poser H (2005) The prediction problems in the complex sciences, in complexity and integrative science. Koyo-Shobo, Kyoto, pp 3–26 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky A (1972) Elimination by aspects: a theory of choice. Psychol Rev 79:281–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weidlich W (2006) Sociodynamics: a systematic approach to mathematical modeling in the social sciences. Harwood Academic Publishers, Amsterdam (The Gordon and Breach Publishing Group). [Reprinted by Taylor and Francis (2002); Paper edition, Dover Publications (2006); Japanese translation, Morikita Shuppan (2007)]

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuji Aruka .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Aruka, Y. (2011). The Moral Science of Heterogeneous Economic Interaction in Face of Complexity. In: Aruka, Y. (eds) Complexities of Production and Interacting Human Behaviour. Physica, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2618-0_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics