Skip to main content

Neoclassical Growth Theory and Standard Models

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Growth in the Regions of Europe

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE,volume 1))

  • 807 Accesses

Abstract

Thoughts and theories on economic growth can be traced back to the classical economists of the eighteenth and nineteenth century, whose works are briefly reviewed alongside the transition to neoclassical growth theory in Sect. 2.1. The basic outline of neoclassical growth models as first developed by Solow (1956) and Swan (1956) is presented in Sect. 2.2. The familiar but nonetheless special case of a Cobb-Douglas production function is examined in Sect. 2.3 in connection with the derivation of steady state levels of factors of production and output. Finally, Sect. 2.4 examines the inclusion of human capital as an additional factor of production and provides a note on endogenous growth theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Smith famously exemplifies this with the production of pins.

  2. 2.

    “Das Kapital hat Kapital produziert.”

  3. 3.

    It is also interesting to note that political arguments in defence of declining wage shares (i.e. rising rates of surplus value) nowadays often go like this: “The wage share may decline, but workers are still better off because wages and salaries continue to grow at real terms” (see, for instance, Der Standard, July 21, 2007, p. 32: “…die Verdienste der unselbständig Beschäftigten [schrumpfen] – statistisch gesehen – nicht. Ihre Einkommen wachsen nur langsamer als Kapital- und Unternehmensgewinne.”).

  4. 4.

    The issue of what is actually “big enough” becomes relevant again when dealing with regions, and will be explored in Sect. 6.1.

  5. 5.

    Gross national income is conceptually identical to gross national product.

  6. 6.

    Except for the possibility that there is no physical capital at all, which corresponds to the second intersection of the two lines at the point of origin in Fig. 2.1. As this mathematically possible equilibrium represents a non-existing economy, it is of no further interest.

  7. 7.

    A formal proof for the stability of the equilibrium can be found in Krelle (1988).

  8. 8.

    The term steady state reminds one of the stationary state as discussed in Sect. 2.1. The difference is that at steady state, an economy continues to grow at constant rate along the steady state growth path. Note that growth at constant rates also includes the possibilities of zero or even negative growth.

  9. 9.

    This residual has become known as the Solow residual.

  10. 10.

    Definitions and discussions of the various ways of implementing technological progress in a neoclassical production function can be found in Beckmann and Künzi (1984).

  11. 11.

    The terms “abstract knowledge”, “state of technology” and, if appropriate, “effectiveness of labour” are usually used as synonyms here as well as in the bulk of growth literature.

  12. 12.

    The term human capital (“Humankapital”) has been voted Ghastly Neologism of the Year 2004 (“Unwort des Jahres”) in Germany, which provoked some controversy. It should be stressed that the jury was appalled by non-technical applications of the expression (Spiegel Online, 18th January 2005 (http://www.spiegel.de/kultur/gesellschaft/0,1518,337259,00.html, queried on 30-July-2007)).

  13. 13.

    In analogy to Sect. 2.2, the possibility of initial values of either type of capital equalling zero is ignored.

  14. 14.

    A formal proof of the stability of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model can be found in Gandolfo (1997).

  15. 15.

    Economic history is somewhat reflected in these two most important neoclassical growth models: the Solow model adjusts the focus on physical capital accumulation, and provides an explanation of worldwide economic growth after the Second World War; the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model adds a focus on human capital accumulation to the former, and provides an explanation of worldwide economic growth since the decline of industrial employment in Western Europe and North America. Seen from a meta-level, these two models perfectly mirror their respective ages of economic development.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin XX (1995) Economic growth. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckmann MJ, Künzi HP (1984) Mathematik für Ökonomen III – Analysis in mehreren Variablen. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York, NY and Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang A, Wainwright K (2005) Fundamental Methods of mathematical economics, 4th edn. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Domar ED (1946) Capital expansion, rate of growth, and employment. Econometrica 14(2):137–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandolfo G (1997) Economic dynamics, 3rd edn. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg and New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrod RF (1939) An essay in dynamic theory. Econ J 49(193):14–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inada K-I (1963) On a two-sector model of economic growth: comments and a generalization. Rev Econ Stud 30(2):119–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König H (1997) Innovation und Beschäftigung. In: Vosgerau, H-J (ed) Zentrum und Peripherie – Zur Entwicklung der Arbeitsteilung in Europa. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Krelle W (1988) Theorie des wirtschaftlichen Wachstums, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York, NY and Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Krelle W, Gabisch G (1972) Wachstumstheorie. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg and New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr (July 1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr (1990) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am Econ Rev 80(2):92–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (May 1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107:407–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1872) Das Kapital – Kritik der politischen Ökonomie; Erster Band: Der Produktionsprozeß des Kapitals, 2nd edn, Reprint 2003. Parkland, Cologne

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1885) Das Kapital – Kritik der politischen Ökonomie; Zweiter Band: Der Zirkulationsprozeß des Kapitals, 2nd edn, Reprint 2003. Dietz, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1894) Das Kapital – Kritik der politischen Ökonomie; Dritter Band: Der Gesamtprozeß des Kapitals Reprint 2003. Dietz, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti LL (1960) A mathematical formulation of the Ricardian system. Rev Econ Stud 27(2):78–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1821) On the principles of political economy and taxation, 3rd edn, Reprint 1996. Prometheus, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer D (1996) Advanced macroeconomics. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(2):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1926) Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, 2nd edn, Reprint 1987. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy German edition 1993: A. Francke Verlag, Tübingen and Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations German edition 2003: Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70(1):65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39(3):312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swan TW (1956) Economic growth and capital accumulation. Econ Rec 32(2):334–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank (2004a) World Development Report 2005. The World Bank and Oxford University Press, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank (2004b) World Development Indicators 2004. The World Bank, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank (2008) Global development finance – the role of international banking. The World Bank, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sascha Sardadvar .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sardadvar, S. (2011). Neoclassical Growth Theory and Standard Models. In: Economic Growth in the Regions of Europe. Contributions to Economics, vol 1. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2637-1_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics