Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Governing China in the 21st Century ((GC21))

Abstract

Based on the preceding literature review, this chapter theorizes the main thesis of this book, that is, the model of "Dual Intergovernmental Transformation for Market Developemnt" (DITMD), and explains the meaning of this new framework. It argues that while decentralization may promote governmental incentives to preserve markets, it also incurs tremendous transaction costs in markets. In order to take advantage of economic benefits of decentralization and also avoid its disadvantages at the same time, this chapter further designs the DITMD model to allocate the state’s coercive powers appropriately in order to sustain market development, theoretically.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Harold Demsetz (2002: 154), for instance, remarks: “Yes, because private owners claim much of the reward and bear much of the cost that accompanies actions they take with their resources, but agents of the state bear only a small fraction of the rewards and costs that accompany the actions they take with state assets; the ultimate bearers of these are not the agents but the country’s citizens. Representatives and administrators in the government may be discharged by voters if they are disappointed with what has been done with the state’s assets, but the costs thus imposed on the state’s agents in the usual case will be quite small relative to those borne collectively by the nation’s citizens if the state’s agents have used state assets poorly. Similarly, the representative who retains his post because citizens like the way he has used state resources receives a reward that is quite small relative to the benefits he has conferred on the country.”

  2. 2.

    But, in the same article, Majone (2001: 103) also articulates that, if the main reason is to reduce decision-making costs, “principals should appoint agents who share their policy preferences.” I am only concerned of market incentives (or “credibility” in Majone’s term) here.

  3. 3.

    Olivier Blanchard and Michael Kremer (1997) label such a process of transformation as “disorganization.”

  4. 4.

    Jonathan A. Rodden (2006: 5) has a similar comment: “In fact, the accountability advantages of decentralization require that the central government’s authority be substantially limited. Industrial organization theorists have shown that in order to strengthen incentives and promote initiative in a decentralized organization, the center must credibly limit its own information and authority. The flip side, however, is a loss of strategic control by the center. In decentralized federations, politically fragmented central governments may find it difficult to solve coordination problems and provide federation-wide collective goods.”

  5. 5.

    From this perspective, students of the state-market relationship usually distinguish two roles of the state in markets, namely, a player vs. a referee. For instance, the World Bank (1997: 30–31) remarks: “What does the state do? For one thing, it sets the formal rules – laws and regulations – that are part and parcel of a country’s institutional environment…These formal rules, along with the informal rules of the broader society, are the institutions that mediate human behavior. But the state is not merely a referee, making and enforcing the rules from the sidelines; it is also a player, indeed often a dominant player, in the economic game. Every day, state agencies invest resources, direct credit, procure goods and services, and negotiate contracts; these actions have profound effects on transaction costs and on economic activity and economic outcomes, especially in developing economies…The state, then, is in a unique position: not only must it establish, through a social and political process, the formal rules by which all other organization must abide; as an organization itself, it, too, must abide by those rules (emphasis added).” In this analysis, I separate the role of the state in sponsoring market activities from the broader category of the role of state that has been traditionally regarded as a referee.

References

  • Adler, Paul S., “Market, Hierarchy, and Trust: The Knowledge Economy and the Future of Capitalism,” Organization Science, Vol. 12, No. 2, 2001, pp. 215–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, Armen A., “Property Rights,” in David R. Henderson ed., The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Liberty Fund, 2008, online available at http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/PropertyRights.html

  • Alchian, Armen A., & Harold Demsetz, “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organizations,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 5, 1972, pp. 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, Pranab, “The Nature of Institutional Impediments to Economic Development,” Center for International and Development Economics Research Working Paper No. C96-066, “Decentralization of Governance and Development,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No. 4, 2002, pp. 185–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benham, Alexandra, & Lee Benham, “The Costs of Exchange,” Ronald Coase Institute Working Paper Series, No.1, July 2001, online available at http://www.coase.org/workingpapers/wp-1.pdf

  • Blanchard, Olivier, & Michael Kremer, “Disorganization,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4, 1997, pp. 1191–1126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, Olivier, & Andrei Shleifer, “Federalism with and without Political Centralization: China Versus Russia,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 48, 2001, pp. 171–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, Alfred D., Jr., “The Beginnings of ‘Big Business’ in American Industry,” The Business History Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press, 1977.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, Ronald H., “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, Vol. 4, No. 16, 1937, pp. 386–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, Ronald H., “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, 1960, pp. 1–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlman, Carl J., “The Problem of Externality,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, 1979, pp. 141–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, Harold, “Toward a Theory of Property Rights,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, “Property Rights,” in Peter Newman ed., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 3, Hants: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002, pp. 144–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dollery, Brian, & Wai Ho Leong, “Measuring the Transaction Sector in the Australian Economy, 1911–1991,” Australian Economic History Review, Vol. 38, No. 3, 1998, pp. 207–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller, Michael A., “The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets,” Harvard Law Review, Vol. 111, No. 3, 1998, pp. 621–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, Michael C., & William H. Meckling, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3, Issue 4, 1976, pp. 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, Janos, The Socialist System: the Political Economy of Communism, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Majone, Giandomenico, “From the Positive to the Regulatory State: Causes and Consequences of Changes in the Mode of Governance,” Journal of Public Policy, Vol. 17, No. 2, 1997, pp. 139–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majone, Giandomenico, “Two Logics of Delegation: Agency and Fiduciary Relations in EU Governance,” European Union Politics, Vol. 2, No. 1, 2001, pp. 103–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mertha, Andrew C., “China’s ‘Soft’ Centralization: Shifting Tiao/Kuai Authority Relations,” The China Quarterly, Vol. 184, 2005, pp. 791–810.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montinola, Gabriella, Yingyi Qian, & Barry R. Weingast, “Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political Basis for Economic Success in China,” World Politics, Vol. 48, No. 1, 1995, pp. 50–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naughton, Barry J., & Dali L. Yang eds., Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Dent Era, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, Douglas C., Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: Norton, “Government and the Cost of Exchange in History,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 44, No. 2, 1984, pp. 255–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, Douglass C., & Barry R. Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitment: the Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 49, No. 4, 1989, pp. 803–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates, Wallace E., Fiscal Federalism, New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, “Toward A Second-Generation Theory of Fiscal Federalism,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 12, 2005, pp. 349–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, Mancur, “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3, 1993, pp. 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouchi, William G., “Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans,” Administratively Science Quarterly, Vol. 25, No. 1, 1980, pp. 129–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, Walter W., “Neither Market Nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization,” Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 12, 1990, pp. 295–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prud’homme, Remy, “The Dangers of Decentralization,” The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 10, No. 2, 1995, pp. 201–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Yingyi, & Barry R. Weingast, “China’s Transition to Markets: Market-Preserving Federalism, Chinese Style,” Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 1, Issue 2, “Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 4, 1997, pp. 83–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, G. B., “The Organisation of Industry,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 82, No. 327, 1972, pp. 883–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochlitz, Michael, Vera Kupina, Thomas Remington, & Andrei Yakovlev, “Performance Incentives and Economic Growth: Regional Officials in Russia and China,” Eurasian Geography and Economics, Vol. 56, No. 4, 2015, pp. 421–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, Jonathan, “Comparative Federalism and Decentralization: On Meaning and Measurement,” Comparative Politics, Vol. 36, No. 4, Hamilton’s Paradox: The Promise and Peril of Fiscal Decentralization, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, Jonathan, & Susan Rose-Ackerman, “Does Federalism Preserve Markets?” Virginia Law Review, Vol. 83, No. 7, Symposium: The Allocation of Government Authority, 1997, pp. 1521–1572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheiber, Harry N., “The Road to Munn: Eminent Domain and the Concept of Public Purpose in the State Courts,” in Donald Fleming & Bernard Bailyn eds., Law in American History, Boston: Little, Brown, “Federalism and the American Economic Order, 1789–1910,” Law & Society Review, Vol. 10, No. 1, Essays in Honor of J. Willard Hurst: Part One, 1975, pp. 57–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheiber, Harry N., “Xenophobia and Parochialism in the History of American Legal Progress: from the Jacksonian Era to the Sagebrush Rebellion,” 23 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 625 (1981–1982).

    Google Scholar 

  • Skowronek, Stephen, Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Administrative Capacities, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, Daniel, The Architecture of Government: Rethinking Political Decentralization, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, John Joseph, & Douglass C. North, “Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy, 1870–1970,” in Stanley L. Engerman & Robert E. Gallman eds., Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1986, pp. 95–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, Barry R., “The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, Vol. 11, No. 1, 1995, pp. 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, Barry R., “Second Generation Fiscal Federalism: The Implications of Fiscal Incentives,” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 65, Issue 3, 2009, pp. 279–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wibbels, Erik, Federalism and the Market: Intergovernmental Conflict and Economic Reform in the Developing World, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, Oliver E., “Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 1, Markets and Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York: Free Press, 1975.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, Oliver E., “Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 22, No. 2, 1979, pp. 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, Oliver E., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York: Free Press, 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank, World Development Report 1997: The State in A Changing World, New York: Oxford University Press, 1997.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Cheng, J. (2019). Dual Intergovernmental Transformation for Market Development. In: States, Intergovernmental Relations, and Market Development. Governing China in the 21st Century. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-58357-4_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics